Xiang Wu 1, 2 and Jinlong Zhang 1, 2, 3
Academic Editor:Carlo Piccardi
1, School of Management, Huazhong University of Science & Technology, Wuhan 430074, China
2, Modern Information Management Center, Huazhong University of Science and Technology, 1037 Luoyu Road, Wuhan 430074, China
3, Collaborative Innovation Center for Modern Logistics and Business of Hubei, Wuhan Technology and Business University, Wuhan 430065, China
Received 28 March 2015; Accepted 28 June 2015; 9 July 2015
This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
1. Introduction
When introducing a new repeat-purchase product into the market, the firm faces a complicated demand pattern. First, the new product diffuses in the market and more and more consumers begin to adopt the product. The Bass model assumes that consumers are influenced by two kinds of communication: mass media and word of mouth [1]. The first consumer group is only influenced by mass media (also called "external influence"), while the other group is only influenced by word of mouth (also called "internal influence"). The external influence reflects the initiative of consumers in adopting the new product, while the internal influence characterizes the imitation behavior in adoption. Second, the demand consists of two parts: the trial purchase from the new adopters and the repeat purchase from the existing adopters [2]. Finally, price decisions also influence how the product diffuses [3]. If the firm charges a lower price, it earns less for a unit product but harvests more sales volumes derived from the trial and repeat purchase. Thereby, the firm should get an in-depth understanding of the demand evolution and carefully choose the price level.
The firm can use dynamic lot sizing strategy to deal with dynamic demands derived from the diffusion process, that is, reviewing the inventory periodically and deciding whether to replenish products. The firm makes ordering decisions with regard to the demand at each period, which partly depends on the firm's pricing decisions. Thus, both the ordering and pricing decisions are essential for new repeat-purchase products. We consider two scenarios: (1) two-stage decision scenario, in which the sales division determines a price to maximize the gross profit and the purchasing division makes ordering decisions to minimize the total cost subsequently, and (2) joint decision scenario, in which the firm makes pricing and ordering decisions simultaneously to maximize the profit. In each scenario, we consider how the new product diffusion patterns and repeat-purchase rate influence ordering and pricing decisions. Usually, the ratio of the internal influence to the external influence has large variation for different products while the sum of these two influences does not [4]. Hence, we focus on the effects of the following two factors: the ratio of internal influence to the external influence and the repeat-purchase rate.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. We discuss the relevant literature in the next section. In Section 3, we use dynamic lot sizing model and generalized Bass model to formulate both two-stage and joint decision models. In Section 4, we give an upper and lower bound of the optimal price for both models and develop heuristic algorithms to solve them. We give a case with sensitivity analysis in Section 5 and make concluding remarks in Section 6.
2. Literature Review
Our study mainly relates to two research domains: the Bass model with price effects and joint inventory and pricing models.
The underlying premise of the Bass model lies in that the probability of adoption of a new product for nonadopters at each period linearly depends on two forces: innovators (or "external influence") and imitators (or "internal influence") [1]. The number of previous adopters positively influences the latter force but has no impact on the former one. The Bass model has both continuous and discrete forms, allowing us to examine product diffusion process under various circumstances [1, 5]. Besides, pricing new products requires a thorough understanding of the complex dynamics associated with product diffusion process [3, 6]. We adopt the discrete form of the Bass model and consider product diffusion in a much broad setting with dynamic lot sizing and pricing decisions. Very few studies combine the Bass model with inventory decisions, except Bilginer and Erhun [7] and Bhattacharya et al. [8].
This research also closely relates to the growing research stream on joint pricing and inventory management (see the review paper of Yano and Gilbert [9]). Scholars investigate joint decisions in various setting, such as perishable or substitutable products [10], noninstantaneous decaying items [11, 12], backorder [13], weather-sensitive demand [14], and demand uncertainty [15]. We contribute to this research stream by considering joint pricing and ordering decisions in the new repeat-purchase product setting.
3. Ordering and Pricing Models
3.1. Problem Description
We consider a firm selling a new repeat-purchase product in the following [figure omitted; refer to PDF] periods. The new repeat-purchase product has its own diffusion pattern characterized by the Bass model and also influenced by the price. Thus, the firm makes ordering and pricing decisions based on the understanding of new repeat-purchase product diffusion process.
This paper considers two models: (1) two-stage decision model, in which the sales division determines a price to maximize the gross profit and the purchasing division makes ordering decisions subsequently, and (2) joint decision model, in which the firm makes pricing and ordering decisions simultaneously to maximize the profit.
3.2. Assumptions and Denotations
We assume that the consumer purchases at most one unit of the new product at each period and uses the following denotations:
: [figure omitted; refer to PDF] : total periods of the planning horizon;
: [figure omitted; refer to PDF] : index for periods, [figure omitted; refer to PDF] ;
: [figure omitted; refer to PDF] : demand at period [figure omitted; refer to PDF] ;
: [figure omitted; refer to PDF] : inventory at the end of period [figure omitted; refer to PDF] ;
: [figure omitted; refer to PDF] : order size at period [figure omitted; refer to PDF] ;
: [figure omitted; refer to PDF] : a binary indicator variable, [figure omitted; refer to PDF] if an order occurs at period [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and [figure omitted; refer to PDF] if not;
: [figure omitted; refer to PDF] : number of new adopters at period [figure omitted; refer to PDF] ;
: [figure omitted; refer to PDF] : cumulative number of adopters by period [figure omitted; refer to PDF] ;
: [figure omitted; refer to PDF] : repeat-purchase rate;
: [figure omitted; refer to PDF] : set-up cost at period [figure omitted; refer to PDF] ;
: [figure omitted; refer to PDF] : unit ordering cost at period [figure omitted; refer to PDF] ;
: [figure omitted; refer to PDF] : unit holding cost at period [figure omitted; refer to PDF] ;
: [figure omitted; refer to PDF] : market potential for the new product, defined as the possible largest amount of consumers;
: [figure omitted; refer to PDF] : coefficient of innovation;
: [figure omitted; refer to PDF] : coefficient of imitation.
3.3. Demand
We use the discrete form of the Bass model with the price effect to describe how the new repeat-purchase product diffuses. The number of the adopters at period [figure omitted; refer to PDF] is [3, 5] [figure omitted; refer to PDF]
The Bass model assumes that consumers are influenced by two kinds of communication: mass media and word of mouth . The first consumer group is only influenced by mass media (also called "external influence"), while the other group is only influenced by word of mouth (also called "internal influence"). Since [figure omitted; refer to PDF] consumers still have not adopted the product by period [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , the adoption rate at period [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , consists of two parts: [figure omitted; refer to PDF] represents adoption from those who are only influenced by mass media and [figure omitted; refer to PDF] represents adoption from those who are influenced by the existing adopters that make up a proportion of [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . The last term, [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , characterizes the effect of price on product diffusion. When [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . In consequence, [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and [figure omitted; refer to PDF] represent the diffusion parameter given price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] .
For [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , the demand at period [figure omitted; refer to PDF] consists of two parts: the trial purchase from new adopters and the repeat purchase from the cumulative adopters. We further assume that the price influences the trial purchase and repeat purchase in the same way. Thereby, the demand derived from repeat purchase would be [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . When offering very low prices, the firm makes at most all cumulative adopters purchase repeatedly. In consequence, the demand from repeat purchase is [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . Thus, the demand at period [figure omitted; refer to PDF] is [figure omitted; refer to PDF]
3.4. A Two-Stage Decision Model
In the first stage, the sales division determines an optimal constant price to maximize the gross profit: [figure omitted; refer to PDF]
The demand is defined as (2). Thus, the model is [figure omitted; refer to PDF]
The sales division solves the optimal price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and thus determines the demand [figure omitted; refer to PDF] .
In the second stage, the purchasing division makes ordering decisions to minimize the total cost: [figure omitted; refer to PDF] The total cost at period [figure omitted; refer to PDF] includes the total order cost [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and the inventory holding cost [figure omitted; refer to PDF] .
The inventory balance equation is [figure omitted; refer to PDF] where [figure omitted; refer to PDF] is the demand at period [figure omitted; refer to PDF] given price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . We further assume that there is no inventory at the beginning of the planning horizon: [figure omitted; refer to PDF]
Besides, both inventory level and order size are nonnegative: [figure omitted; refer to PDF]
Thus, the purchasing division solves the following model: [figure omitted; refer to PDF]
The decision variable of this model is the order size [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , and [figure omitted; refer to PDF] .
3.5. Joint Decision Model
In the joint decision model, the firm considers pricing and inventory decisions simultaneously to maximize the profit: [figure omitted; refer to PDF]
Therefore, the model is [figure omitted; refer to PDF]
The decision variables of this model are the price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , [figure omitted; refer to PDF] at each period [figure omitted; refer to PDF] .
4. Algorithm
We denote [figure omitted; refer to PDF] to be the minimum unit order cost over the planning horizon and give an upper and lower bound for the optimal price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] by the following lemma.
Lemma 1.
For both the two-stage and joint decision models, the optimal price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] satisfies [figure omitted; refer to PDF] .
Proof.
The firm charges a price at least to make net profit; that is, [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . On one hand, the price must cover all costs including unit order cost; that is, [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . On the other hand, the price should ensure the existence of demand; that is, the number of cumulative adopters [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . Since [figure omitted; refer to PDF] we have [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and thus obtain [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . Therefore, the optimal price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] satisfies [figure omitted; refer to PDF] for both the two-stage and joint decision models. Considering the complexity of the new product pricing problems [16], we develop heuristic algorithms for both models.
4.1. Algorithms for the Two-Stage Decision Model
In the two-stage decision model, the firm makes pricing and ordering decisions by two steps. First, the sales division finds an optimal price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] to maximize the gross profit [figure omitted; refer to PDF] by solving model (4). Second, the purchasing division determines an optimal ordering decision to minimize the total cost by solving model (9). We now give algorithms for models (4) and (9).
We use the following Gaussian Random-Walk search algorithm to solve model (4):
(1) Start with [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , an initial price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , and calculate the gross profit [figure omitted; refer to PDF] given the demand [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . Set the initial best price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and the initial best gross profit [figure omitted; refer to PDF] .
(2) Draw [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . Jump to Step 3 if [figure omitted; refer to PDF] ; otherwise, repeat Step 2.
(3) Calculate the gross profit [figure omitted; refer to PDF] given the demand [figure omitted; refer to PDF] .
(4) If [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , update the best price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , the best gross profit [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , reset [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , and jump to Step 2. Otherwise, jump to Step 5.
(5) Compute [figure omitted; refer to PDF] .
(6) Consider [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . [figure omitted; refer to PDF] with probability [figure omitted; refer to PDF] (move) and one has [figure omitted; refer to PDF] with probability [figure omitted; refer to PDF] (stay). Update [figure omitted; refer to PDF] accordingly.
(7) Stop if [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . Otherwise, jump to Step 2.
This algorithm stops if the best gross profit [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and the best price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] have not been improved after [figure omitted; refer to PDF] random walks. In Step 6, [figure omitted; refer to PDF] transits to [figure omitted; refer to PDF] if [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . Even if [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , [figure omitted; refer to PDF] transits to [figure omitted; refer to PDF] with probability [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . This mechanism automatically seeks out price areas with high gross profit and makes the price walk freely in the interval [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . We choose [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , after experiment trials in our numerical case.
We solve model (9) by the Wagner-Whitin algorithm, a classic dynamic lot sizing algorithm proposed by Wagner and Whitin [17].
4.2. Algorithm for the Joint Decision Model
Since [figure omitted; refer to PDF] indicates whether to replenish product at period [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , we term it as "order policy" to facilitate our algorithm development. Given any price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , we are able to know the demand [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and thus model (11) becomes the standard dynamic lot sizing model, which could be solved by the Wagner-Whitin algorithm [17].
We denote the order policy under price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] as [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , considering that we can determine the uniquely optimal order policy [figure omitted; refer to PDF] for any given [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . Assume that the firm charges price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] but uses order policy [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , the optimal order policy under price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . In this case, we can easily solve the order size at each period [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . We denote [figure omitted; refer to PDF] as the profit for charging price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] but use order policy [figure omitted; refer to PDF] .
Then, we propose the following algorithm to solve model (11):
(1) Set [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and select an initial price, [figure omitted; refer to PDF] .
(2) Calculate the demands given by [figure omitted; refer to PDF] for [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . Use the Wagner-Whitin algorithm to determine an optimal ordering policy [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and the profit [figure omitted; refer to PDF] .
(3) For the ordering policy [figure omitted; refer to PDF] derived in Step 2, use a Gaussian Random-Walk algorithm to find a price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] to maximize [figure omitted; refer to PDF] .
(4) Calculate the profit increase [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . Set [figure omitted; refer to PDF] .
(5) Stop if [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , where [figure omitted; refer to PDF] is a small enough positive number; otherwise, jump to Step 2.
Note that the firm should determine both the price and the ordering decisions. Our algorithm keeps one decision (price or ordering policy) unchanged and improves the profit [figure omitted; refer to PDF] by varying another decision. Step 3 keeps the order policy [figure omitted; refer to PDF] constant and varies the price to improve the profit [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . Similarly, Step 2 keeps the price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] constant and adjusts the order policy to improve the profit [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . Thus, every iteration in the algorithm helps improve the profit [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . The stop rule is that there is no improvement in profit [figure omitted; refer to PDF] (i.e., [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , where [figure omitted; refer to PDF] in Step 5). The Gaussian Random-Walk search algorithm in Step 3 is very similar to that in the two-stage decision model, and we only need to replace [figure omitted; refer to PDF] as [figure omitted; refer to PDF] .
From a practical viewpoint, the price can be only integer multiples of the smallest unit of currency. Therefore, we can also search all integer multiples of the smallest currency unit between [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and find the optimal price. It reports very similar results with Gaussian Random-Walk search algorithm, suggesting the reliability of the latter one. Thus, we only report results obtained from the Gaussian Random-Walk search algorithm in this paper.
5. Numerical Case
We choose a packaged imported food item called "Zespri Kiwifruit" from Netherlands provided by an online fresh produce retailer in Central China. The unit order cost [figure omitted; refer to PDF] (the currency unit is Chinese Yuan Renminbi (CNY) in our paper), setup cost [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , unit holding cost [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , and the number of periods [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . The retailer charges a regular price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , and the repeat-purchase rate [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , the market potential [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , and the price parameter [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . We set external influence [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and internal influence [figure omitted; refer to PDF] as suggested by Sultan et al. [4].
In the two-stage decision model, the sales division determines an optimal constant price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] to maximize the gross profit by solving model (4). Then, the purchasing division determines an optimal ordering decision given demand [figure omitted; refer to PDF] to minimize total cost by solving model (9). We use these results as a baseline to evaluate potential benefits of the joint decision model, in which the firm determines pricing and ordering decisions simultaneously by solving model (11).
5.1. Pricing and Ordering Decisions for Both Models
We report the optimal pricing and ordering decisions for both models in Table 1. The firm charges the optimal price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and earns profit [figure omitted; refer to PDF] for the two-stage decision model and charges the optimal price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and earns profit [figure omitted; refer to PDF] for the joint decision model. Besides, the order policy [figure omitted; refer to PDF] of the two models is also different: the firm replenishes this kind of repeat-purchase product at [figure omitted; refer to PDF] in the two-stage decision model, but it does not in the joint decision model.
Table 1: Comparison of the optimal pricing and ordering decisions.
| [figure omitted; refer to PDF] | [figure omitted; refer to PDF] | [figure omitted; refer to PDF] | [figure omitted; refer to PDF] | [figure omitted; refer to PDF] | [figure omitted; refer to PDF] | [figure omitted; refer to PDF] | [figure omitted; refer to PDF] | [figure omitted; refer to PDF] | [figure omitted; refer to PDF] | [figure omitted; refer to PDF] | [figure omitted; refer to PDF] |
Two-stage decision model: [figure omitted; refer to PDF] | ||||||||||||
[figure omitted; refer to PDF] | 1 | 0 | 0 | 1 | 0 | 1 | 1 | 1 | 1 | 0 | 1 | 0 |
[figure omitted; refer to PDF] | 2529 | 0 | 0 | 5512 | 0 | 4062 | 4298 | 4077 | 7617 | 0 | 7480 | 0 |
[figure omitted; refer to PDF] | 374 | 629 | 1011 | 1500 | 1946 | 2022 | 1502 | 720 | 226 | 55 | 12 | 2 |
[figure omitted; refer to PDF] | 374 | 1003 | 2014 | 3514 | 5460 | 7482 | 8984 | 9704 | 9930 | 9985 | 9997 | 9999 |
[figure omitted; refer to PDF] | 374 | 769 | 1386 | 2253 | 3259 | 4062 | 4298 | 4077 | 3852 | 3765 | 3743 | 3737 |
| ||||||||||||
Joint decision model: [figure omitted; refer to PDF] | ||||||||||||
[figure omitted; refer to PDF] | 1 | 0 | 0 | 1 | 0 | 1 | 0 | 1 | 1 | 0 | 1 | 0 |
[figure omitted; refer to PDF] | 1757 | 0 | 0 | 3457 | 0 | 5890 | 0 | 3412 | 6549 | 0 | 6087 | 0 |
[figure omitted; refer to PDF] | 297 | 459 | 689 | 988 | 1318 | 1577 | 1617 | 1350 | 890 | 469 | 209 | 84 |
[figure omitted; refer to PDF] | 297 | 756 | 1445 | 2433 | 3751 | 5328 | 6945 | 8295 | 9185 | 9654 | 9863 | 9947 |
[figure omitted; refer to PDF] | 297 | 547 | 913 | 1417 | 2040 | 2691 | 3199 | 3412 | 3353 | 3196 | 3075 | 3012 |
Joint decision model evaluates all costs and revenue and thus finds a better way to price and order this kind of imported food. Comparing to the two-stage decision, joint ordering and pricing decisions bring in substantially extra profit (as large as [figure omitted; refer to PDF] ). Since the two-stage decision model maximizes the gross profit, the sales division tends to charge a lower price to increase the sales volume. We find that both the number of new adopters [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and the demand [figure omitted; refer to PDF] are larger for two-stage decision model. However, the increase in sales volume does not ensure profitability. In consequence, cooperation between the sales division and the purchasing division turns out valuable.
Since the diffusion process and repeat-purchase rate are important for repeat-purchase products, we also conduct sensitivity analysis for these two factors and examine their effects on the optimal price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and the profit [figure omitted; refer to PDF] .
5.2. The Influences of [figure omitted; refer to PDF]
The internal influence [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , the external influence [figure omitted; refer to PDF] , and the price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] jointly determine the diffusion process of repeat-purchase products when the market potential [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and the price parameter [figure omitted; refer to PDF] keep constant (see (1)). Consumers show initiative to adopt some repeat-purchase products, but they become hesitant to adopt others. That is, the internal influence [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and the external influence [figure omitted; refer to PDF] vary from different repeat-purchase products. Particularly, [figure omitted; refer to PDF] has large variation for different products while [figure omitted; refer to PDF] does not [4]. In consequence, we keep [figure omitted; refer to PDF] constant and examine the effects of [figure omitted; refer to PDF] .
We show how the optimal price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and the profit [figure omitted; refer to PDF] vary with [figure omitted; refer to PDF] in Figure 1. We observe that joint decision model makes the firm charge higher prices and earn more profits than two-stage decision model for all [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . Since joint decision model takes all kinds of costs rather than only unit order cost into consideration, the firm has less space to offer low prices. However, cooperation between the sales division and the purchasing division makes the pricing and ordering decisions wiser and thus obtain more profits.
Figure 1: The influences of [figure omitted; refer to PDF] .
(a) [figure omitted; refer to PDF]
[figure omitted; refer to PDF]
(b) [figure omitted; refer to PDF]
[figure omitted; refer to PDF]
Besides, both the optimal price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and the profit [figure omitted; refer to PDF] show a decreasing trend with [figure omitted; refer to PDF] for both models. When the ratio of the internal influence to the external influence [figure omitted; refer to PDF] increases, consumers in the market show less innovativeness and more imitativeness. Thus, the firm should charge low prices to promote the product diffusion process and results in profit reduction.
5.3. The Influences of Repeat-Purchase Rate [figure omitted; refer to PDF]
Repeat-purchase rate varies from different kinds of repeat-purchase products. Various factors such as reputation of the firm, product quality, service quality, and demographic variables may influence the repeat-purchase rate [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . Since both [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and the price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] influence the demand from cumulative adopters, the firm should understand how to adjust prices with regard to the repeat-purchase rate.
We show how the optimal price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] and the profit [figure omitted; refer to PDF] vary with [figure omitted; refer to PDF] in Figure 2. We find that joint decision model makes the firm charge higher or at least of the same prices and earn more profits than two-stage decision model for all [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . Similarly, we contribute this observation to the value of cooperation between the sales and the purchasing divisions.
Figure 2: The influences of repeat-purchase rate [figure omitted; refer to PDF] .
(a) [figure omitted; refer to PDF]
[figure omitted; refer to PDF]
(b) [figure omitted; refer to PDF]
[figure omitted; refer to PDF]
Interestingly, the optimal price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] decreases first, increases later, and keeps constant eventually with [figure omitted; refer to PDF] for both two-stage and joint decision models. First, when the repeat-purchase rate is low (i.e., [figure omitted; refer to PDF] in Figure 2(a)), the firm should reduce prices with the increase of [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . Low prices can increase both the number of new adopters and the number of cumulative adopters who show repeat-purchase behavior, and the latter effect becomes greater when the repeat-purchase rate increases. Thus, the optimal price [figure omitted; refer to PDF] decreases with [figure omitted; refer to PDF] when repeat-purchase rate is low. Second, when the repeat-purchase rate is fairly high (i.e., . [figure omitted; refer to PDF] in Figure 2(a)), the firm should increase prices with the increase of [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . Since the high repeat-purchase rate and low prices can at most make all cumulative adopters purchase this kind of imported food, the firm does not need to lower prices when [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . Instead, the firm will increase prices with [figure omitted; refer to PDF] when the repeat purchase is fairly high. Finally, when the repeat-purchase rate is very high (i.e., [figure omitted; refer to PDF] in Figure 2(a)), the firm will keep a constant, high price. The firm does not increase prices again because higher prices would shapely reduce the number of new adopters. Thus, they keep a constant, high price in this case.
The profit [figure omitted; refer to PDF] increases at first and keeps constant eventually with [figure omitted; refer to PDF] . When the repeat-purchase rate is not very high (i.e., [figure omitted; refer to PDF] in Figure 2(b)), the profit increases with [figure omitted; refer to PDF] since the repeat-purchase behavior of the cumulative adopters increases. When repeat-purchase rate is very high (i.e., [figure omitted; refer to PDF] in Figure 2(b)), however, the profit keeps constant since all cumulative adopters purchase this kind of imported food.
6. Concluding Remarks
This paper studies ordering and pricing problems for new repeat-purchase products. We incorporate the repeat-purchase rate and price effects into the Bass model to characterize the demand of repeat-purchase products. We consider both two-stage and joint decision models, apply them to a specific imported food provided by an online fresh produce retailer in Central China, and solve them by Gaussian Random-Walk and Wagner-Whitin based algorithms.
Three results are worthy of attention. First, joint pricing and ordering decisions bring more significant profits than making pricing and ordering decisions sequentially (as large as 17.81 percent in our case). Second, a great initiative in adoption significantly increases price premium and profit. When the ratio of the internal influence to the external influence increases, both th price and the profit decrease. Thus, the firm should make efforts to increase the initiative in adoption. Finally, the optimal price shows a U-shape (i.e., decreases first and increases later) relationship and the profit increases gradually with the repeat-purchase rate when it is still not very high (i.e., [figure omitted; refer to PDF] ). Thus, it is worthwhile for the firm to improve repeat-purchase rate to a fairly high level.
Acknowledgment
The financial support from the National Natural Science Foundation Program of China [no. 71271095] is gratefully acknowledged.
Conflict of Interests
The authors declare that there is no conflict of interests regarding the publication of this paper.
[1] F. M. Bass, "A new product growth for model consumer durables," Management Science , vol. 15, pp. 215-227, 1969.
[2] C. Stummer, E. Kiesling, M. Günther, R. Vetschera, "Innovation diffusion of repeat purchase products in a competitive market: an agent-based simulation approach," European Journal of Operational Research , vol. 245, no. 1, pp. 157-167, 2015.
[3] B. Robinson, C. Lakhani, "Dynamic price models for new-product planning," Management Science , vol. 21, no. 10, pp. 1113-1122, 1975.
[4] F. Sultan, J. U. Farley, D. R. Lehmann, "A meta-analysis of applications of diffusion models," Journal of Marketing Research , vol. 27, pp. 70-77, 1990.
[5] V. Mahajan, E. Muller, F. M. Bass, "New product diffusion models in marketing: a review and directions for research," Journal of Marketing , vol. 54, no. 1, pp. 1-26, 1990.
[6] F. M. Bass, T. V. Krishnan, D. C. Jain, "Why the bass model fits without decision variables," Marketing Science , vol. 13, no. 3, pp. 203-223, 1994.
[7] Ö. Bilginer, F. Erhun, "Production and sales planning in capacitated new product introductions," Production and Operations Management , vol. 24, no. 1, pp. 42-53, 2015.
[8] S. Bhattacharya, V. D. R. Guide Jr., L. N. Wassenhove, "Optimal order quantities with remanufacturing across new product generations," Production and Operations Management , vol. 15, no. 3, pp. 421-431, 2006.
[9] C. A. Yano, S. M. Gilbert, "Coordinated pricing and production/procurement decisions: a review," Managing Business Interfaces , pp. 65-103, Springer, 2004.
[10] L. Lu, J. Zhang, W. Tang, "Optimal dynamic pricing and replenishment policy for perishable items with inventory-level-dependent demand," International Journal of Systems Science , pp. 1-15, 2014.
[11] C.-T. Yang, L.-Y. Ouyang, H.-H. Wu, "Retailer's optimal pricing and ordering policies for non-instantaneous deteriorating items with price-dependent demand and partial backlogging," Mathematical Problems in Engineering , vol. 2009, 2009.
[12] R. Maihami, I. N. Kamalabadi, "Joint pricing and inventory control for non-instantaneous deteriorating items with partial backlogging and time and price dependent demand," International Journal of Production Economics , vol. 136, no. 1, pp. 116-122, 2012.
[13] Q. Feng, S. Luo, D. Zhang, "Dynamic inventory-pricing control under backorder: demand estimation and policy optimization," Manufacturing & Service Operations Management , vol. 16, no. 1, pp. 149-160, 2014.
[14] H. Fu, B. Dan, X. Sun, "Joint optimal pricing and ordering decisions for seasonal products with weather-sensitive demand," Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society , vol. 2014, 2014.
[15] P. Berling, V. Martinez-de-Albeniz, "Optimal inventory policies when purchase price and demand are stochastic," Operations Research , vol. 59, no. 1, pp. 109-124, 2011.
[16] T. V. Krishnan, F. M. Bass, D. C. Jain, "Optimal pricing strategy for new products," Management Science , vol. 45, no. 12, pp. 1650-1663, 1999.
[17] H. M. Wagner, T. M. Whitin, "Dynamic version of the economic lot size model," Management Science , vol. 5, no. 1, pp. 89-96, 1958.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer
Copyright © 2015 Xiang Wu and Jinlong Zhang. Xiang Wu et al. This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Abstract
This paper studies ordering and pricing problems for new repeat-purchase products. We incorporate the repeat-purchase rate and price effects into the Bass model to characterize the demand pattern. We consider two decision models: (1) two-stage decision model, in which the sales division chooses a price to maximize the gross profit and the purchasing division determines an optimal ordering decision to minimize the total cost under a given demand subsequently, and (2) joint decision model, in which the firm makes ordering and pricing decisions simultaneously to maximize the profit. We combine the generalized Bass model with dynamic lot sizing model to formulate the joint decision model. We apply both models to a specific imported food provided by an online fresh produce retailer in Central China, solve them by Gaussian Random-Walk and Wagner-Whitin based algorithms, and observe three results. First, joint pricing and ordering decisions bring more significant profits than making pricing and ordering decisions sequentially. Second, a great initiative in adoption significantly increases price premium and profit. Finally, the optimal price shows a U-shape (i.e., decreases first and increases later) relationship and the profit increases gradually with the repeat-purchase rate when it is still not very high.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer