Journal of Economic Structures (2014) 3:9
DOI 10.1186/s40008-014-0009-9
R E S E A R C H Open Access
Received: 3 March 2014 / Accepted: 18 November 2014 / 2015 Sato; licensee Springer. This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/2.0
Web End =http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/2.0 ), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Abstract This paper presents an integrated energy balance model of global and urban warming in the attributes/functionings framework la GormanLancasterSen and proposes a Global Warming Function and an Urban Warming Function. Also presented is a concept of Heat Island Integral, which measures the difference of anthropogenic heat stocks between two regions. The model involves residents, producers such as ofces and manufacturers, and landscape gardeners who play a very important role in cooling down by roof-top gardening and tree-planting activities, etc. It is shown that urban warming tax/subsidy scheme is designed as a Groves mechanism by the implementation theory.
Keywords Anthropogenic heat stocks Attributes/characteristics la
GormanLancaster Biological attributes Global warming function Heat island
integral Landscape gardener Microclimate Sens functionings Urban warming
function Urban warming tax/subsidy scheme
JEL Classication H2 Q24 R13 R14
1 Introduction
An urban heat island is represented by isoterms on a map joining points of equal temperature and it is an analogy of contours of above and beneath the sea. By using the concept of Heat Island Integral that I introduce below, formal denitions of a heat island and a cool island are given in Sect. 2.3.1
1See Gartland (2008) for a comprehensive treatment of the urban heat island.
K. Sato (B)
College of Liberal Arts, International Christian University, 3-10-2 Osawa, Mitaka-shi, Tokyo 181-8585, Japane-mail: [email protected]
Anthropogenic Climate Change in an Integrated Energy Balance Model of Global and Urban Warming
Kimitoshi Sato
Page 2 of 21 K. Sato
In the past 100 years, the temperature has risen 0.9 C in Japan and 3.2 C in Tokyo.2 Whereas the temperature increase of Paris and New York are, respectively, about 0.9 C and 1.6 C for the same period. Tokyos urban warming rate was remarkable; it is above the rising rate of the past ten thousand years. The Tokyo Metropolitan Research Institute for Environmental Protection estimated that the heat emitted from cars and air conditioners has resulted in a temperature increase of 0.4 C and from the loss of greenery it has increased by 1.4 C in the past century. The green area of Japan was halved from 1930 to 1990, thus, there has been an increase in radiant heat and a decrease in radiation cooling. There is therefore a pressing need to manage the urban thermal pollution due to urban warming in many cities of Japan. See Sato (2013) for biohazards and health risks suffered from urban thermal pollution.
In this paper, let me present a model to provide an optimal amount of heat as an urban public good. In order for this model to be operational, necessity compels us to devise a tax/subsidy scheme to determine the sum of emissions of heat released by metropolises into the urban atmosphere. The urban environment should now be perceived to be an intergenerational public good that we have to protect. Large cities such as Tokyo, Osaka, Sendai, Hiroshima, Fukuoka, Nagoya, and Sapporo consume a huge amount of energy by using cars and air conditioners, hence, urban warming has now become notable. Metropolitan residents are to be involved in the problem of urban warming which is now conrmed to be caused by emissions of enormous heat, i.e., all the households living in cities could be polluters as well as victims of the warming climate. Any local government is in charge of controlling the total amount of heat emitted by residents and producers to keep the urban climate not too warm in the near future.
This paper proposes to consider urban atmosphere as a complex of intangible attributes such as heat and gases, and the goods composed of tangible attributes that are produced by rms, and green areas consisting of owers and trees as biological attributes supplied by landscape gardeners.
The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents an integrated energy balance model of global and urban warming in the attributes/functionings framework la GormanLancasterSen and proposes an Urban Warming Function. Also presented is the concept of Heat Island Integral, which measures the difference of anthropogenic heat stocks between two regions. The model involves residents, producers such as ofces and manufacturers, and landscape gardeners, who play a very important role to cool down by roof-top gardening and tree-planting activities, etc. It is shown that an urban warming tax/subsidy scheme is designed as a Groves mechanism by the implementation theory. Finally some remarks follow, including some technological innovations.
2Urban heat islands exist in Tokyos central business districts (CBD) such as Otemachi, Shinjuku, and Shibuya. The Imperial Palace, the Meiji Shrine, and the Shinjuku Gyoen National Garden are Cool Islands, and the temperature of these areas remains rather low compared to the hotter spots mentioned above. Japan has warmed by 0.6 C in these three decades. See Howard (1833, 1837) for the case of England and Renou (1862, 1868) for the case of France.
Journal of Economic Structures (2014) 3:9 Page 3 of 21
2 Urban Warming and Heat Island
2.1 A Model of Urban Warming and Heat Island
This section introduces the attributes/characteristics model based on the Gorman Lancasterian theory where goods are regarded as a composition of characteristics.3 All trace gases such as greenhouse gases (GHGs) can be interpreted as gaseous attributes in our framework, since they innitesimally compose the urban atmosphere as an urban public good. Characteristics of urban climate are in order: pollution substances, solar radiation, cloudiness, precipitation, temperature, absolute and relative humidity, and wind velocity. These attributes compose the urban planetary boundary layer. This paper focuses upon heat as an attribute, since it is the main cause of urban warming. Before rushing into our theoretical model, let me introduce some basic concepts of urban warming and heat islands.
Let us consider a city where we analyze urban warming and heat islands and the related problems occurring in urban and suburban areas. For the sake of simplicity, assume that our city is composed of two areas, i.e., the urban area and the suburban area, which are divided into many regions, B = {1, . . . , B}: the set of regions.
Assume that any size whatever can be chosen for a region.Let there be N residents indexed by i N = {1, . . . , N}: the set of inhabitants
who live in both urban and suburban areas. Each individual emits heat and trace gases when consuming goods or services indexed by j and its set is J = {1, . . . , J }.
For the sake of simplicity, it is assumed that each producer j supplies only one good j which is composed of C characteristics indexed by c C = {1, . . . , C}: the set of
tangible attributes. Denote as qjc an amount of attribute c embodied in one unit of good j. There are producers: e.g., ofces, hotels, and manufacturers.
Suppose that resident i chooses a landscape gardener named to have a part of his/her land planted with trees and owers, and = {1, . . . , } is the set of gar
deners. Dene q s as a biomass of species s in one cube meter supplied by landscape gardener , and S = {1, . . . , S} as the set of species of ora and fauna as biological at
tributes. Let xij be resident is consumption of good j, and Vi be his/her demand for the plants supplied by landscape gardener , thus, xi = (xi1, . . . , xiJ , Vi ) is his/her
consumption vector. There is also a local government whose task is to reduce heat emissions by making effective use of an urban warming tax scheme as dened below. No need to mention, every inhabitant, producer, and landscape gardener resides in some house or construction in region , so that an index will be omitted hereafter in almost all the cases, except for describing some variables related to region .
Different from von Thnen (1826), or the usual urban economic theory, our city is hypothesized as follows:
H1. The city is formed in a heterogeneous plain, where the climate differs among its regions.
3For the New Consumer Theory, see Gorman (1956/1980), Gorman and Myles (1987), and Lancaster (1966, 1971, 1991). See also Hagen (1975), Drze and Hagen (1978), and Pendleton and Shonkwiler (2001).
Page 4 of 21 K. Sato
H2. The city is not necessarily circular and its center is called the Central BusinessDistrict.
H3. Its urban and suburban transportation systems are available in any direction whatsoever.
H4. Residents commute to work for an ofce in the CBD or in suburbs.
H5. Landscape gardeners plant in a part of the lands of residents and producers. H6. Manufacturers produce goods in the suburban area.
The urban atmosphere is regarded as a complex of gaseous attributes including GHGs, which are to be mainly generated by production and consumption activities. The amount of gases such as N2 and O2 are stationary, so I can focus upon heat and trace gases as attributes in this paper. Let G = {C + 1, . . . , C + G} be the set of trace
gases which compose the urban atmosphere.
Taking urban warming into consideration, let us extend and generalize the framework developed by Sato (2006, 2008). Inhabitants emit heat and gases, qih 0 and
qig 0, g G, which are resident is unit emissions of heat and gas. Hence, qihVi
and qigVi , g G, are individual is emitted quantities of heat and gas in his/her
consumption of Vi units of greening service . Resident is consumption of gas and heat as attributes are, respectively, given by
zig = qig[parenleftbigg][summationdisplay]
jJ
and
xij + Vi [parenrightbigg], g G (1)
xij + Vi [parenrightbigg]. (2)
When producing one unit of good, each producer cannot choose but jointly emit trace gases as vexing by-products, qjg 0, which is producer js unit emission of
gas. Thus, qjgxj is js amount emitted of gas when it produces xj units of good j. qjgxj and qjhxj producer js amounts of gas and heat in his/her production of goods. One observes therefore
zjg = qjgxj . (3)
Similarly, when producing one unit of good, each producer must jointly emit heat as an annoying by-product, qjh 0, which is producer js unit emission of heat.
Thus, qjhxj is producer js amount emitted of heat when it produces xj units of good j. One obtains therefore
zjh = qjhxj . (4)
Landscape gardeners also emit heat and gases, q h 0 and q g 0, g G, which
are gardener s unit emissions of heat and any gas. Hence, q gV and q hV are gardener s emitted quantity of a gas and heat, respectively, in his/her provision of V units of greening service . We have
z g = q gV (5)
zih = qih[parenleftbigg][summationdisplay]
jJ
Journal of Economic Structures (2014) 3:9 Page 5 of 21
and
z h = q hV . (6)
Let zi0 be resident is available time that he/she possesses, by which he/she utilizes other characteristics. In other words, any characteristic cannot be utilized without using time. Note that dioxide (CO2) can be reduced by g which is an amount of CO2 xed in trees, i.e., the net carbon gain.4 Amounts of each tangible attribute embodied in the goods and intangible attributes in the atmosphere, which are consumed by metropolitan agents are given for any c C, for any g G, and for heat:
zic = [summationdisplay]
jJ
z g gg, (8)
g = 1 if g = CO2 and g = 0 if g = CO2,
z h. (9)
In the above equations, zic means the consumption of tangible attributes which compose goods, while zg and zh represent the total amount of a trace gas and heat emitted by all residents, producers and gardeners. Note also that the values of zg,
g G, and zh can be measured in tons or kilojoules. Heat and gases are generated
both in the consumption and production of goods and services. Every inhabitant is made to consume not only his/her emissions but also the quantity emitted by the rest of the city. When he/she uses goods, he/she emits heat and gases. They are already released when the goods are made by producers and greening services are provided by landscape gardeners.
The above three equations may be interpreted as characteristics availability functions which convert commodities into attributes. In the framework of this paper, any good j can be recognized as (xj , qj1, . . . , qjC+G) and any greening service can be
represented as (V , q C+1, . . . , q C+G, q C+G+1, . . . , q C+G+S). The amount of any
characteristic associated with each good and service can be regarded as a parameter that is objective and common to all consumers, i.e., it has the public-good property. Thus, the inhabitants as consumers must behave as price and quality takers, since they can only change their consumption of zic, zih, and zig, via the choice of xij and
Vi , given the price and the quality of each good and service. Producers and gardeners can choose the composition of attributes embedded in their goods and their greening services.
The following notation is used in what follows.
T : temperature (C)
4See Hof et al. (1990) and Sato (2006) for the xation of CO2 in trees.
qjcxij, (7)
zg = [summationdisplay]
iN
zig + [summationdisplay]
jJ
zjg + [summationdisplay]
and
zh = [summationdisplay]
iN
zih + [summationdisplay]
jJ
zjh + [summationdisplay]
Page 6 of 21 K. Sato
Al: planetary albedo (0.3) determining how much of the incoming energy is reected by the atmosphere
: solar constant (1372 W m2) : emissivity (assumed to be 1)
: StefanBoltzmann constant (5.67108 W m2 K4) [the outgoing ux is T 4
by the StefanBoltzmann Law]
K (kelvin): 273.15 K = 0 C
: anthropogenic heat stocks at region [J]
T t: temperature increase at region at time t [C] cp: specic heat capacity [1004.2 J/kg C]u, v: coordinates [m]
M: atmospheric density [1.293 kg m3]
A: airshed of region [m3]
Ab: a coefcient (0.3) determining how much of the energy which is not absorbed by the surface of the earth
2.2 Global Warming Function
It is observed that warming of cities is mainly due to heat emissions and partly due to global warming, and the GHGs concentrations affect the latter. These effects therefore must be incorporated in the model of urban and global warming.
As was mentioned in Sect. 2.1, zg, g G, is the total quantity of each GHG re
leased all over the world. A part, gzg, 0 < g < 1, g G, of an aggregate emission
of trace gas g, is observed to go to the atmosphere and the rest, (1 g)zg, is per
ceived to be absorbed by the oceans and forests as carbon sinks, if g is carbon dioxide. Of this amount, about 43 % of the CO2 emissions are observed to be absorbed. The mass of the gth GHG staying in the atmosphere is gzg, g G. The disintegra
tion rate or an inverse of an atmospheric lifetime of each trace gas is denoted as g, 0 < g < g, g G.
One problem of the GHGs is that they are not ows (emissions), but stocks (concentrations). Let t [0, ) be the time argument. Denote t0 as a base year. Let
g > 0, g G, be a conversion parameter from mass (GtC/year) to concentration
(ppm), then the latter at time t is represented by
tg = [integraldisplay]
t
t0
. (11)
In the sequel, let me follow Greiner (2004a, 2004b) for global warming in an endogenous growth model, originally due to Roedel (2001).
The most basic energy balance model is presented as follows:
T = [braceleftbigg]
(1 Al)
4
g g[parenrightbig]zg d, g G. (10)
So one observes a vector of GHGs concentrations as stocks:
Zt = [parenleftbig]
t 1, . . . , tG
g
1372 0.7
4 5.67 108 [parenrightbigg]1/4 =
255 K = 18 C. (12)
1/4
= [parenleftbigg]
Journal of Economic Structures (2014) 3:9 Page 7 of 21
This is the temperature without the greenhouse effect. Following Greiner (2004a, 2004b), the difference between the outgoing ux and the incoming radiative ux is given by
F =
19.95
109 . (13)
The average surface temperature on earth with the greenhouse effect can be calculated by
T = [braceleftbigg]
(1 Al)Ab
4F
1372 0.21
4 5.67 108 (19.95/109)[parenrightbigg]1/4
= 288 K = 15 C. (14) Thus, the above calculations lead us to conclude that the greenhouse effect for the earth is 33 C. Next we incorporate the effect of GHGs concentrations to global warming. Let CO2 be an actual concentration of CO2 at time t and 0CO2 its concentration at the Pre-industrial Revolution: e.g., the former is 377 ppm in 2004 and the latter is 280 ppm in 1750. IPCC (1990) assumed that the radiative forcing (W m2)
of carbon dioxide is given by
t tCO2[parenrightbig] =5.35 ln
tCO2/1750CO2
1/4
= [parenleftbigg]
. (15)
For the sake of simplicity, we take two main GHGs: CO2 and nitrous oxide. Let g be a Global Warming Potential and g is an inverse of an atmospheric lifetime compared with CO2 (CO2 = 1 and CO2 = 1). According to Michaelis (1990), nitrous oxides
contribution to global warming is gg = 58/12 = 29/6 compared with CO2. We
remark that the global warming depends on the stocks (concentrations) Zt of GHGs:
t Zt[parenrightbig] = 5.35
[summationdisplay]
gG
. (16)
It is observed that the average surface temperature on earth with global warming can be calculated by
T 2004 = [bracketleftbigg]
(1 Al)Ab + 5.35{ln(2004CO2/1750CO2) + (29/6) ln(2004N2O/1750N2O)} 4F
gg ln
tg/1750g
1/4
1372 0.21 + 5.35{ln(1.35) + (29/6) ln(1.18)}
4 5.67 108 (19.95/109) [bracerightbigg]1/4
= 290 K = 17 C. (17) Compare the two values of temperature, i.e., 15 C and 17 C. The difference is 2 C, which is attributable to the effect of GHGs concentrations between the years 1750 and 2004.
The above arguments lead us to dene the Global Warming Function,
W
t
Zt[parenrightbig][parenrightbig] = [braceleftbigg](1 Al)Ab + t(Zt) 4F
1/4, (18)
= [braceleftbigg]
Page 8 of 21 K. Sato
which represents the average surface temperature on earth with the global warming due to the buildup of GHGs concentrations.5
2.3 Heat Island Integral
The problem of how to represent anthropogenic heat stocks in any block was analyzed in Sato (2006) who introduced the concept of Heat Island Integral. Here a new version is proposed. In effect, there are differences in the temperature of building surface, back alleys, roof-tops, streets, and green tracts of land, which are directly exposed to the solar radiation. These differences of the surface temperature of the ground coverage can be measured by utilizing infrared cameras or remote sensing.
A formula is proposed for heat as a stock in this subsection. It is the microclimate surrounding a construction, which most inuences any agent who resides or works in any region. However, climatical incidents depend not only upon the heat stocks in each region, but also upon those in the entire city. More precisely, it is the sum of developable areas of the ground coverage, e.g., streets, tree crowns, roof-tops, and walls of the buildings which exist in region . Denote r and r(u, v) as the area and the height of construction r in region , respectively, and R as the set of constructions.
Suppose is an urban commercial region and is a suburban residential region.
The Riemann sum has led me to propose a concept of Heat Island Integral (HII) between regions and :
HII = cpM [summationdisplay]
rR
A T [integraldisplay][integraldisplay]rr(u, v) du dv
A T [integraldisplay][integraldisplay]r r (u, v) du dv[bracerightbigg]. (19)
Needless to say, the existence condition of this multiple integral is that the functions are continuous and compact in the domains r and r , and it is easily seen that
this condition is satised. Region is called a Heat Island if HII > 0. Naturally, it is necessary to consider meteorological conditions peculiar to region , such as the Foehn phenomenon, the convergence of sea breezes, and the transport of the warmed air from other regions, as well as the conguration of the region such as being a basin. Region is called a Cool Island if HII 0.
As T = /cpAM by physics, HII can be rewritten as
HII = [summationdisplay]
rR
5See Schneider (1989) and Graedel and Crutzen (1995) for comprehensive knowledge about the atmosphere and climate change. Sato (2007) presented a model of global warming in the GormanLancaster Sen framework.
r (u, v) du dv[bracerightbigg]. (20)
Remark 1 The difference between Heat Island Intensity and Heat Island Integral is obvious. The former shows the difference of the temperature between two regions,
[integraldisplay][integraldisplay]r
r(u, v) du dv [integraldisplay][integraldisplay]r
Journal of Economic Structures (2014) 3:9 Page 9 of 21
while the latter signies that of the anthropogenic heat stocks between them. The temperature of asphalt and concrete is very often higher than that of the atmosphere in the summertime. It is observed that these materials absorb approximately 70 % of the solar radiation, so that the walls of buildings made of concrete absorb the same amount of heat, which results in urban warming. Thus, an area with a lot of these constructions is apt to become warmer. Notice that concrete is a material which is not at all soon hot, soon cold, but hard to be heated and hard to cool off.
2.4 Urban Warming Function
Let zih be heat emitted by resident i and zjh (z h, resp.) is heat emissions of producer j (landscape gardener , resp.) at region . Any city is composed of regions with anthropogenic heat stocks, = (E), where E = [summationtext]
iN zih +
jJ zjh + [summationtext] z h, B. With E = (E1, . . . , EB), the total heat stocks, (E) = [summationtext]
B (E), may affect agents in any city.
As above, an increase in temperature of an airshed of region is given by the following equation: B
T t =
2106.5 TJ1004.2 J/kg C 621 106 m2 400 m 1.293 kg m3
(1 Al)Ab + 5.35{ln(2004CO2/1750CO2) + (29/6) ln(2004N2O/1750N2O)} 4F
(E2004)
+ cp ATokyo23 M
2106.5 1012 C1004.2 621 106 400 1.293
= 20.26 C. (23)
The difference between this temperature and the average temperature is 3.26 C. It is considered to be attributable urban warming of the average daily anthropogenic heat stocks generated from the 23 wards of Tokyo in August 2004.
anthropogenic heat stocksspecic heat capacity airshed of region atmospheric density
. (21)
In August 2004, the 23 wards of Tokyo generated an anthropogenic heat stocks of 2106.5 TJ/day. It was observed that warm air occupied up to an altitude of 400 m in the summer of Tokyo of which area is 621 km2. We choose this as an airshed and the altitude of 400 m, then the average daily temperature increase is given by
T Aug.2004
Tokyo23
=
. (22)
Adding the above equation to the model to compute the average surface temperature on earth, and one observes
UAug.2004
Tokyo23
= [bracketleftbigg]
1/4
= 17 C +
Page 10 of 21 K. Sato
The greenhouse effect, global warming, and urban warming of any region B
is involved in the function:
Ut = [braceleftbigg]
(1 Al)Ab + t(Zt)
4F
t(Et)cpAM , (24)
which represents the average surface temperature of any region . In the bracket the denominator is given, and the second term varies according to each region. With the inux and outux of energy to earth, the concentrations of GHGs and anthropogenic heat stocks dene the Urban Warming Function Ut. Note that t and t
are functions of stocks of GHGs and anthropogenic heat, respectively. The following assumption is needed.
Assumption 1 For any B, Ut is concave and twice continuously differentiable.
Remark 2 It can easily be seen that Ut/t > 0, 2Ut/(t)2 > 0, /g > 0, 2t/(tg)2 > 0, g G, Ut/ t > 0, and 2Ut/( t)2 > 0, B.
Urban warming is a typical example of a public good which is non-rival but excludable. Its impact on each resident varies from region to region, which can be treated as a regional public good. The global warming function depends upon the anthropogenic heat stocks in region , , and the concentrations Z composed of gaseous attributes of the urban atmosphere.
2.5 Beings and Functionings of Residents
The GormanLancasterian characteristics theory is the most suitable to analyze goods and the urban atmosphere which is perfectly divisible and decomposable as various attributes. However, the characteristics availability functions can be applied to any resident whose utilization differs from person to person. Consequently, each inhabitants functionings should be introduced as one of the important concepts la Sen (1985) to fully appraise the value of goods or their characteristics. Each residents physical and climatical situations differ, so I must introduce the functionings which are represented below.
With time zi0, the amounts of each characteristic embodied in the goods, the plants in the green area, the atmosphere, and the greenery consumed by resident i is given by
zi = [parenleftbig]z
1/4
+
, (25)
where zCi = (zi1, . . . , ziC), zGi = (ziC+1, . . . , ziC+G) and zSi = (ziC+G+1, . . . ,
ziC+G+S).
Denote z = (z1, . . . , zN) and U = (U1, . . . , UB). With consumption externality,
beings of inhabitant i may be representable as
bi = bi[parenleftbig]f
i1(z, U), . . . , fiKi (z, U)
i0, zCi, zGi, zSi, zih
. (26)
Let Ki = {fi1, . . . , fik, . . . , fiKi }, where Ki differs among individuals. The fol
lowing assumption is needed.
Journal of Economic Structures (2014) 3:9 Page 11 of 21
Assumption 2 For any i N, fik Ki is twice continuously differentiable.
2.6 Residents Happiness Function and Valuing Well-Beings
Let any inhabitant i have his/her Happiness Function which is assumed to depend upon his/her being, thus, one observes
Hi = Hi(bi). (27)
Any persons use of functionings can vary his/her being and happiness. Let fik/U and U/ be fikU and U , respectively. Let also /g and U/ be g and U , respectively. Denote g/zig and /zih as gz and z, respectively.
Dene resident is hedonic shadow price or hedonic marginal willingness-to-pay (HMW) of any tangible and intangible characteristic c and of any biological attribute s in greenery, c C, g G, s S:
ic = [summationtext]
kKi (dHi/dbi)(bi/fik)(fik/zic)
kKi (dHi/dbi)(bi/fik)(fik/zi0), (28)
, (29)
kKi (dHi/dbi)(bi/fik)(fik/zis)
kKi (dHi/dbi)(bi/fik)(fik/zi0), (30)
B fikU U z)
Remark 3
(i) ih is a marginal contribution of heat as an attribute to resident is marginal happiness through his/her functionings in terms of his/her available time zi0. It may correspond to a marginal rate of substitution between each attribute and the time zi0 in the utility theoretical context.
(ii) Whether inhabitant i considers a commodity or a service as good, irrelevant, or bad to his or her functionings is conrmed by the sign of
cCG{h} icqjc for
each good j and
ig = [summationtext]
kKi (dHi/dbi)(bi/fik)(fik/zig + [summationtext]
B fikU Uggz)
kKi (dHi/dbi)(bi/fik)(fik/zi0)
is = [summationtext]
and
ih = [summationtext]
kKi (dHi/dbi)(bi/fik)(fik/zih + [summationtext]
kKi (dHi/dbi)(bi/fik)(fik/zi0)
. (31)
cSG{h} icqjc for any service . Moreover, whether a commodity or a service is socially good or not may also be examined by summing over individuals of
cCG{h} icqjc for any good j and [summationtext]cSG{h} icqjc for any service . Now, to keep the room open to the cool air, an air conditioner is one of the necessities for our comfortable urban life under urban warming, even if it does emit heat as a vexing by-product. Consequently, ih < 0 holds for many people who feel displeased by the scorching heat due to urban warming. However, they wish to avoid heat, thus,
cCG{h} icqjc 0 still prevails for j if it is an air conditioner. It cannot be helped, since everybody wants
Page 12 of 21 K. Sato
to keep his/her room cool, especially under a burning sun. It is not only heat but also the resulting high humidity, and actual and sensory high temperatures, that could lower some functionings of residents. This fact can be represented by (dHi/dbi)(bi/fik)
B fikU U z < 0, fik Ki, i N.
3 Optimizations Under Urban Warming and Heat Island
3.1 Residents
Consider that city dwellers know the risks of human-induced future urban climate changes, and that they have an incentive to optimize the composition of the urban atmosphere in order to aim at achieving their personal best-beings in the city where they live and work.
Let e be a generic index for any emitter and E the set of all emitters in any city. Since heat and gases are generated by the use of fossil fuels, let e be emitter es integrated emissions of heat and gases and denote e = (1, . . . , e1, e+1, . . . ,
N+J+). Urban warming is a privately provided regional public good that is sup
plied by individual emitters of heat in the atmosphere. By emitting heat, which means using the urban atmosphere, every metropolitan innitesimally contributes to hot air as an urban public good. The inhabitants and producers in an urban heat island are both members who are forced to join in an urban club.
Denote i(U(i(i), i)) as individual is damage function. A variable i 0 is
the abatement cost associated with his/her effort to avoid damages due to too much warmed urban air by reducing heat and gas emissions. It is assumed that i is known only to individual i. Functionings to cool cities are, for example, economizing in power by reducing the use of electrical ttings and by using a bicycle or a public transportation system instead of a private car. As urban warming accelerates, city dwellers will want to buy newly developed, more efcient air conditioners, which result in reduction of heat emissions. These are examples of functionings which explain i. Resident i has to pay ti(i(i)) as an urban warming tax, in order for the urban atmosphere not to be warmed so much as to be unendurable to live in region . It is natural to consider ti(i(i)) < ti(i(0)), since paying an abatement cost could reduce emissions and his/her tax, which can incite people to behave environment-friendly.
Greening lands and roof-tops belong to the most effective ways to cool micro-climates. The metropolitan government determine 0 < < 1 as the refund rate for planting the vegetation Vi that resident i requests landscape gardener . Assume that the value of is decided by the scientic data about tree-planting. As dened, i is landscape gardener s greening cost per cubic meter of inhabitant is garden, hence, i Vi is resident is greening cost, and i Vi is is refund for the effort to plant trees in his/her garden.
The set J includes all the goods and services such as electricity and water. Let pj be a unit price of good j, then each inhabitants budget constraint is given by
zi0 = [summationdisplay]
jJ
pj xij + i Vi Vi + ti[parenleftbig]
i(i)
[parenrightbig] +
i
U
i(i), i[parenrightbig][parenrightbig].(32)
Journal of Economic Structures (2014) 3:9 Page 13 of 21
The left-hand side of the above equation signies the value of available time whose price is normalized to unity. An assumption is needed.
Assumption 3 For any i N, ti, i, and i are convex, and they are continuously dif
ferentiable, with i/U > 0, U/i > 0, di/di < 0, and dti/di > 0, B.
The more heat is emitted, the more the urban air warms, and the more costly life becomes. This signies that the more damages there are due to urban warming augment, the more residents have to pay for cool air, the more tax they have to pay for alleviating the urban warming. Each residents effort can diminish his/her tax payment. The maximand is the personal happiness function, thus, each resident solves the following optimization problem:
Max Hi = Hi(bi)
s.t. bi = bi[parenleftbig]f
i1(z, U), . . . , fiKi (z, U) [parenrightbig]
U = [braceleftbigg]
(1 Al)Ab + (Z)
4F
1/4
+
(E)cpAsM , B,
zi0 = [summationdisplay]
jJ
pjxij + i Vi i Vi + ti[parenleftbig]
i(i)
[parenrightbig] +
i
U
i(i), i[parenrightbig][parenrightbig],
xij 0, j J, Vi 0, .
The FOCs of the above optimization problem are in order. For any resident i N,
an individually optimal consumption of goods composed by GormanLancasterian tangible and accompanying intangible attributes, and of the vegetation as a complex of biological attributes, is characterized as j J, , B
[summationdisplay]
cCG{h}
icqjc = pj , (33)
[summationdisplay]
cSG{h}
icq c = i (1 ), (34)
dtidi = [summationdisplay]
B
i U
U
i . (35)
Remark 4
(i) The conditions presented are not only necessary but also sufcient from the assumptions on the functions. In the rst equation, ic signies a hedonic shadow price of attribute c acquired by utilizing inhabitant is available time and his/her functionings. The left-hand side of the rst equation is the sum of resident is marginal evaluations of the tangible attributes embodied in one unit of a good, as well as of the gaseous attributes and heat released when the good is produced.
Page 14 of 21 K. Sato
Notice that the rst two formulas verify that any resident considers heat and gases as intangible characteristics emitted when consuming one unit of good j. The rst conditions mean that the unit price of the good is equal to the sum of marginal contributions of attributes to his/her happiness through his/her functionings. The conditions assure a Pareto optimality for a quantity of each good, and they give a basis upon which goods resident i chooses to buy. He or she may not buy good j after due consideration of
cG{h} icqjc, which may be smaller than pj , because icqjc < 0 holds for some c C and
[summationdisplay]
cCG{h}
icqjc <
[summationdisplay]
cC
icqjc = pj . (36)
(ii) The second condition signies that individual is marginal evaluation of species as biological attributes by having the vegetation Vi in the area Ai of his/her land Li, planted by landscape gardener is equal to his/her greening cost per cubic meter minus the refunded cost. The term may be called a urban warming (alleviating) subsidy, since it represents the reward according to the persons effort to plant trees in a part of his/her land. Many residents suffer from the erce heat in summertime, if he/she feels very displeased by the boiling weather due to urban warming.
(iii) The condition about ti shows that city dweller is marginal evaluation of consuming a unit of electricity is a match for his/her marginal urban warming tax. Thus, a proper incentive is given to an inhabitant to have a part of his/her land planted with trees and owers from motives of selshness.
3.2 Ofces and Manufacturers as Producers
Here I present the optimization by prot maximizing producers to supply one good with an optimal product quality to consumers. Let producer j (landscape gardener ) produce good j (service ) by using xj0 (x 0) as inputs, and the price of xj0 (x 0) is normalized to be one, with
jJ xj0 + [summationtext] x 0 [summationtext]iN zi0. Then xj0 (x 0) is the amount of labor time that producer j (landscape gardener ) uses as an input.
Denote j (U(j (j ), j )) as producer js damage function and j 0 is an
abatement cost only known to j. Note that j depends on the emissions of the rest of the city. It may be interpreted as an external cost to buy, for example, more efcient power saving air conditioners. Urban warming tax tj is a function of j and j represents producer js effort to decrease emissions of heat and gases when producing and transporting xj = [summationtext]
iN xij units of good j. More examples to explain j are in
order: producer j encourages his/her staff to commute by bicycle, to use hybrid or fuel cell cars or electric vehicles as delivery vans, and to choose energy-saving types of personal computers in its ofce.
It is generally accepted that midtown hotels and ofce buildings use more computers and air conditioners than residents and landscape gardeners. The former would emit more heat and gases into the urban atmosphere as to cool hotels and ofces, as urban warming accelerates in the near future. As producers, ofces offer services, manufacturers supply products. j Vj is producer js greening cost, and j Vj is the refund to j.
Journal of Economic Structures (2014) 3:9 Page 15 of 21
Let yj = (xj0, xj, qj1, . . . , qjC, qjC+1, . . . , qjC+G, qjh) be producer js input
output vector, then it produces a good j as an output to maximize its prot subject to the production function
j = j (xj0, xj , qj1, . . . , qjC, qjC+1, . . . , qjC+G, qjh) 0, (37)
where qjc, c G, is the amount of heat or a gas emitted in the urban atmosphere
when it produces one unit of good j, and (qjC+1, . . . , qjC+G, qjh) is a vector of
intangible attributes. Meanwhile, (qj1, . . . , qjC) is a vector of tangible characteristics embodied in one unit of good j. Any producer therefore jointly produces goods and attributes. The production function may not be convex, but the difculties arising from non-convexities are not treated here, so an assumption is needed.
Assumption 4 For any j N, j is convex and twice continuously differentiable
with xj0/qjc > 0, c C G {h}, c = j . Furthermore, xj > 0 implies xj0 > 0,
and R+, {yj|j (yj ) 0, xj0 } is compact.
It is assumed that ic and ig are truthful, since all goods are private goods or publicly provided goods such as gas, water, and electricity, for which the residents have to pay public utility charges. Hence, they cannot have them for free.
When xij > 0, pj could be computed as
cCG{h} icqjc from the FOCs, then the prot maximization problem for the producers is given by
Max Pj = [summationdisplay]
iN
[summationdisplay] icqjcxij xj0 j Vj + j Vj tj[parenleftbig]
j (j )
[parenrightbig]
U j (j ), j [parenrightbig][parenrightbig].
Here I make another assumption.
Assumption 5 For any j J, tj , ej and tj are convex, and they are twice contin
uously differentiable with dtj/dj > 0, dj /dj < 0, j /U > 0, U/j > 0,
B.
In the presence of tangible and intangible attributes, the necessary conditions for Pareto optimal product quality in terms of tangible and intangible attributes are for any producer j J: c C, c = j , g G, g = j , h = j
[summationdisplay]
iN
icxij =
xj0
qjc , (38)
[summationdisplay]
iN
j
qjg + [summationdisplay]
B
j U
U
j xj, (39)
[summationdisplay]
iN
igxij =
xj0
qjh + [summationdisplay]
B
j U
U
j xj , (40)
ihxij =
xj0
Page 16 of 21 K. Sato
dtjdj = [summationdisplay]
B
Remark 5
(i) The rst equation establishes a Pareto optimality for an amount of each attribute and determines a vector of optimal tangible characteristics embodied in the good supplied by producer j. The L.H.S. of the rst equation is the marginal revenue which is the aggregate of the residents marginal evaluations of a change in an attribute embedded in xj . Its R.H.S. is the marginal cost in terms of labor time to produce qjc.
i icxij is the marginal social value of good j, which is the sum of the personal evaluations of a change in an attribute when the quantity of good xj is produced.
(ii) The third equation shows a Pareto optimal quantity of each gas as an intangible attribute. The L.H.S. is the social value of heat, and the R.H.S. consists of the terms: the rst two term is the marginal cost in terms of xj0, and the second term means the marginal climatic damage to emit heat. tj is the urban warming tax of producer j.
3.3 Landscape Gardeners
Next, efciency conditions for landscape gardeners are derived. Their job is to plant trees in areas of lands that residents and producers possess, so they are exempted from the obligation of greening a part of their own lands in our model. They supply plants as biological, and thus, tangible attributes, as well as intangible attributes.
Denote (U( ( ), )) as landscape gardener s heat abatement cost and
> 0 is a parameter only known to gardener . Landscape gardeners can attempt to serve green areas to residents and producers by using a new technology which does not emit too much heat. Let N be the set of residents who commission landscape gardener to plant trees and J be the set of producers which ask gardener to plant trees V = [summationtext]
iN Vi + [summationtext]
jJ Vj .
Any gardener provides a green area to residents and producers to maximize his/her prot subject to the production function
= (x 0, L , V , q C+1, . . . , q C+G, q C+G+1, . . . , q C+G+S, q h). (42) Hence, each gardener solves the optimization problem
Max P = [summationdisplay]
iN
+ [parenleftbig]U[parenleftbig]
( ), [parenrightbig][parenrightbig].
Two assumptions are needed for this maximization problem.
Assumption 6 For any , is convex and twice continuously differentiable
with x 0/q c > 0, c S G {h}, c = . Furthermore, A > 0 implies x 0 > 0
and L > 0, and R+, {y | (y ) 0, x 0 , L } is compact.
j U
U
j . (41)
[summationdisplay]
cSG{h}
icq cVi + [summationdisplay]
jJ
j Vj x 0 + t [parenleftbig]
( )
[parenrightbig]
Journal of Economic Structures (2014) 3:9 Page 17 of 21
Assumption 7 For any , t , and are convex and twice continuously differ
entiable with dt /d < 0, d /d < 0, /U < 0 and U/ < 0, B.
The FOCs are the following. For any landscape gardener , necessary con
ditions for Pareto optimal quality of planted vegetation as a complex of biological attributes are s S, s = , g G, g =
[summationdisplay]
iN
isVi + [summationdisplay]
jJ
j Vj
q s =
x 0
q s , (43)
[summationdisplay]
iN
igVi + [summationdisplay]
jJ
j Vj
q g =
x 0
q g + [summationdisplay]
B
U
U
Vi , (44)
[summationdisplay]
iN
ihVi + [summationdisplay]
jJ
j Vj
q h =
x 0
q h + [summationdisplay]
B
U
U
Vi , (45)
dt d = [summationdisplay]
B
U
U
. (46)
Remark 6 The equations establish a Pareto optimality for the amount of each attribute and determine a vector of optimal quality characteristics that any gardener can supply its biological product to residents and producers. In the second and third equations, the R.H.S. are composed of two terms: the rst is the marginal cost of the labor to supply one unit of plant as a biological attribute and the second term is gardener s marginal contribution to urban warming by emitting heat. The L.H.S. of the equations signify the marginal social value in terms of the labor time, where the marginal social value is the sum of the evaluations of a change in each biological characteristic.
3.4 Urban Warming Tax and Subsidy
This section proposes an urban warming (alleviating) tax/subsidy scheme. For that purpose, dene the monetary damages due to urban warming as the sum of costs to deal with public damages: [summationtext]
B D(U). Examples are the economic losses
due to the deaths of people and the inundation of subway stations. embraces houses ooded above oor level or up to the oorboards at some blocks and domesticated animals due to heat waves. The total cost to cope with private damages: [summationtext]
eE e(U) includes the costs of cooling installations in stockyards and of in
creasing water consumption due to cooling them. The social damage due to urban warming therefore is the following. Hence, our problem of social cost to be minimized is
Min { + }.
An assumption is imposed.
Assumption 8 D is concave and twice continuously differentiable with D/ U > 0 and 2D/U2 > 0, B.
Page 18 of 21 K. Sato
Suppose that emissions of heat and gases are integrated to be represented by one argument e zeg zeh. We seek for the socially optimal amount of heat emissions.
We have
[summationdisplay]
B
D(U) U
U e
dedae dae + [summationdisplay]
eNJ
[summationdisplay]
B
e(U) U
U e
dedae dae = 0. (47)
Here is the main result.
Theorem 1 Urban Warming Tax is a mechanism of the form la Groves represented by, e N J , B:
te(e) = [integraldisplay]
e
0
dedae dae + Ie(e),
where Ie(e) is a constant of integration independent of e.6
Proof By adopting the Laffont (1982) differential method, one observes from the FOCs above that
[summationdisplay]
eNJ
e(U) U
e(U) U
U e
Ue[parenrightbigg] + dte(e) de
dedae dae = 0, B. (48)
Integrating this yields
[summationdisplay]
eNJ
te(e) = [integraldisplay]
[braceleftbigg] [summationdisplay]
0 eNJ
e(U) U
dedae dae + Ie(e)[bracerightbigg]. (49)
Removing the summation from Eq. (49) leads the statement of Theorem 1. Suppose that there exists a unique solution to the above problem of social cost minimization. As we aim to nd the urban warming tax corresponding to the social optimum, substituting Eq. (47) in Eq. (49) gives
[summationdisplay]
eNJ
te(e) = [summationdisplay]
B
e
U e
[integraldisplay]
e
0
D(U) U
U e
dedae dae + I, (50)
where I is a constant of integration.
Consequently, the sum of urban warming tax is represented by
[summationdisplay]
eNJ
te(e) = [summationdisplay]
B
D(T) + S, (51)
where S is a constant of integration.
6See Groves (1976), Green and Laffont (1979), and Myles (1995).
Journal of Economic Structures (2014) 3:9 Page 19 of 21
In the above equation, S interpreted as the amount of subsidy can be refunded to those collaborating on tree-planting plus the costs of public utilities. Let me propose therefore the following.
Claim 1 Urban Warming Subsidies are given to the collaborators who have planted trees and vegetation to cool their city. We have
S = [summationdisplay]
iN
[summationdisplay]
ii Vi + [summationdisplay]
jJ
[summationdisplay]
j j Vj .
Subsidies are, respectively, given to residents, ofces, and manufacturers, since they have cooperated in their efforts to have trees and owers planted in the required percentage of their land lots. An important feature is that the tax levied may fully cover social damages, and the part of the tax paid S can be redistributed to the contributors in order to cool their city.
4 Final Remarks
This paper has analyzed urban warming and heat island in the theory of attributes/functionings la GormanLancasterSen that I proposed in Sato (2008). My discussion has proceeded on the premise that the urban atmosphere is a composite of intangible characteristics including heat. This paper has extended Sato (2006, 2008) to combine global and urban warming and the urban heat island in an integrated energy balance model. Our model incorporates landscape gardeners who are commissioned by residents and producers. Then an optimization by each agent is solved to derive optimality conditions in the attributes/functionings theory. Residents are happiness maximizers and producers and landscape gardeners are prot maximizers, and the metropolitan government is a social cost minimizer. An urban warming tax/subsidy scheme has been proposed; the subsidy is given to contributors of cooling the city, by planting. This paper has also shown that the change of composition of tangible attributes in the goods changes that of intangible attributes such as heat and GHGs in the urban atmosphere.
As a recent technological innovation, let me introduce the photocatalyst of titanic oxide (TiO2) to cool-down structures. This method claried that water can be decomposed only by photo energy and titanic oxide. In 2006, an experiment was conducted on a roof-top (10 m2) of a building, which was covered by a water lm coated with titanic oxide. This test proved that this lm of water could cool the building and showed that the temperature decreased by 30 C. More precisely, that experiment veried that the mercury stood at 60 C without the photocatalyst and water sprinkling, whereas the temperature was 30 C with both. The maximum temperature difference between the two cases amounted to 30 degrees. The indoor temperature at that time was 15 C, which resulted in the cost reduction of air conditioning. The photocatalyst of titanic oxide on glass on the sides of the buildings can cool down their structures and save on the cost of air conditioning. The cooling effect and cost effectiveness could be augmented by utilizing rainwater and by coating windows with titanic oxide. Currently, the size of the market for this technology amounts to 0.4 billion dollars, and it is anticipated to augment to 8.3 billion dollars in the future. In 2006 also, a new variety
Page 20 of 21 K. Sato
of photocatalyst has been discovered; applying the radiant energy resolves water to raise hydrogen, which is well known as an ultimate clean energy. A cocatalyst added to yellow powder as a composite of nitrogen gallium and zinc oxide becomes a catalyst which reacts by radiant energy. The resolution efciency of water is about ten times higher than the former one and there is still room for enhancing further efciency. In 2009, a new system of photocatalysis, the titania photocatalyst sheet was invented.
In 2008, it was proposed that a Sierpinsi manifold could be an alternative to the leaves of trees to cool down warming cities by discovering the fractal similarity of the former and the latter. Seen from one direction, a Sierpinski manifold is a plane, whereas it is three-dimensional when it is seen from the other. By selecting a tree, it has been observed that its fractal is two-dimensional, although it has a three-dimensional structure. Samples of the Sierpinski manifold were made and placed on the roof of a building in a central business district in a city and obtained the desired result of cooling down by mitigating solar heat and light under their structure. It was veried that the trees have two fractal dimensions which are the same as the Sierpinski Tetrahedron. A roof as a complex of many Sierpinski tetrahedrons could be a substitute to trees, in terms of an efcient method to combat against urban warming and heat island. Some experiments were conducted by constructing roofs made by Sierpinski tetrahedrons and showed that the temperature beneath these roofs was lower than that measured on a road without the roofs. What is important is that maintenance and waterworks are not necessary for these manifolds, which could save on the cost of water. Different from trees, water is not necessary and just the management of roofs is needed.7
As in Green et al. (2007), we must challenge ourselves to work towards stabilizing the urban climate by reducing anthropogenic heat stocks in regions of cities at all costs. We cannot foresee what will happen in the near future, so we had better take every precaution against urban warming and heat islands.
Competing Interests
The author declares that they have no competing interests.
Acknowledgements An earlier version of this paper was presented at the annual meeting of the Society for Environmental Economics and Policy Studies held at the Graduate School of Environmental Sciences, Tohoku University, September 16, 2012. Its revised version was presented at the autumn meeting of the Japanese Economic Association held at Kanagawa University, September 16, 2013. The author gratefully acknowledges Professor Toyoaki Washida for his useful comments and suggestions at that meeting. Some revisions were made thereafter.
References
Drze J, Hagen K (1978) Choice of product quality: equilibrium and efciency. Econometrica 46:493513 Gartland L (2008) Heat islands: understanding and mitigating heat in urban areas. Earthscan, London
7See Sato (2014) for water-related technological innovations.
Journal of Economic Structures (2014) 3:9 Page 21 of 21
Gorman W (1956/1980) A possible procedure for analyzing quality differentials in the egg market. Journal paper 3129, Iowa Agricultural Experiment Station; Rev Econ Stud 47:843856
Gorman W, Myles D (1987) Characteristics. In: Eatwell J, Milgate M, Newman P (eds) The new Palgrave dictionary of economics. Macmillan, London, pp 403406
Graedel T, Crutzen P (1995) Atmosphere, climate, and change. W. H. Freeman and Company, New York Green C, Baksi S, Dilmaghani M (2007) Challenges to a climate stability energy future. Energy Policy
35:616626
Green J, Laffont J-J (1979) Incentives in public decision-making. Studies in public economics, vol 1.North-Holland, Amsterdam
Greiner A (2004a) Anthropogenic climate change in a descriptive growth model. Environ Dev Econ 9:645662
Greiner A (2004b) Global warming in a basic endogenous growth model. Environ Econ Policy Stud 6:4973
Groves T (1976) Information, incentives, and the internalization of production externalities. In: Lin S (ed)
Theory and measurement of economic externalities. Academic Press, New York, pp 6383Hagen K (1975) On the optimality of the competitive market system in an economy with product differentiation. Swed J Econ 77:443458Hof J, Rideout D, Binkley D (1990) Carbon xation in trees as a micro optimization process: an example of combining ecology and economics. Ecol Econ 2:243256Howard L (1833) Climate of London deduced from meteorological observations, 3rd edn. Harvey and
Darton, London
Howard L (1837) Seven lectures on meteorology. J Lucas Printer, Market-Place, PontefractIPCC (1990) Climate change: the IPCC scientic assessment. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Laffont J-J (1982) Cours de thorie microconomique, volume 1 fondements de leconomie publique.
Editions Economica, Paris. The revised and translated version: Bonin J, Bonin H (1988) Fundamentals of public economics. MIT Press, CambridgeLancaster K (1966) A new approach to consumer theory. J Polit Econ 74:132157. Reprinted as Chap 2 in
Lancaster (1991)
Lancaster K (1971) Consumer theory: a new approach. Columbia University Press, New YorkLancaster K (1991) Modern consumer theory. Edward Elgar, HantsMichaelis P (1990) Global warming: efcient policies in the case of multiple pollutants. Environ Resour
Econ 2:6178
Myles G (1995) Public economics. Cambridge University Press, CambridgePendleton L, Shonkwiler J (2001) Valuing bundled attributes: a latent characteristics approach. Land Econ
77:118129
Renou E (1862) Diffrences de temperature entre Paris et Choisy-le-Roi. Annu Soc Fr 10:105109 Renou E (1868) Diffrences de temperature entre la Ville et la Compagne. Annu Soc Fr 14:8397 Roedel W (2001) Physik unsere Umwelt Die Atmosphre. Springer, BerlinSato K (2006) Urban heat island: an environmental economic modeling. J Heat Isl Inst 1:4045Sato K (2007) Incentives in the hedonic MDP procedures for the global warming as a composition of gaseous attributes. Presented at the workshop of the environment of CORE at lUniversit Catholique de Louvain, April 19; also presented at the regional science workshop in Sendai held at the Graduate School of Information Sciences, Tohoku University, July 26.
Sato K (2008) Cooling the Metropolis: an economic analysis to alleviate urban heat island. J Heat Isl Inst3:115
Sato K (2013) Biohazards and health risks due to urban warming. Presented at the annual meeting of the
Society for Environmental Economics and Policy Studies, held at Kobe University, September 23. Sato K (2014) Ambivalence of water: benecial and detrimental features. In: Langager M, Hashimoto J
(eds) Water literacy: what will the next generation need to know? Monograph series, vol 7. International Christian University IERS, Tokyo, pp 2533Schneider S (1989) Global warming: are we entering a greenhouse century? Sierra Club Books, San FranciscoSen A (1985) Commodities and capabilities. Elsevier, Amsterdamvon Thnen J (1826) Der isolierte Staat in Beziehung auf Landwirtschaft und Nationalkonomie: Untersuchungen ber den Einu, den die Getreidepreise der Reichtum, des Bodens und die Abgaben auf den Ackerbau ausben. Friedrich Perthes, Hamburg. English translation: Wartenberg C (1966) Von Thnens isolated state. Pergamon Press, Oxford
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer
Journal of Economic Structures is a copyright of Springer, 2015.
Abstract
This paper presents an integrated energy balance model of global and urban warming in the attributes/functionings framework à la Gorman-Lancaster-Sen and proposes a Global Warming Function and an Urban Warming Function. Also presented is a concept of Heat Island Integral, which measures the difference of anthropogenic heat stocks between two regions. The model involves residents, producers such as offices and manufacturers, and landscape gardeners who play a very important role in cooling down by roof-top gardening and tree-planting activities, etc. It is shown that urban warming tax/subsidy scheme is designed as a Groves mechanism by the implementation theory.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer