This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
1. Introduction
With the development of information network technology and social media, service-sharing platforms have flourished in just a few years [1]. For example, these platforms include Airbnb, Uber, Upwork, TaskRabbit, and Thumbtack [2]. Service providers rent their idle capacity to consumers through online platforms, thus saving social resources and increasing total welfare [3]. According to a PwC report, the global revenue of service-sharing platforms will reach $335 billion [4]. Therefore, with the rapid development of the platform economy and the increase in Internet users, service sharing has attracted the interest of academia, professionals, and the public [5–7].
In P2P service-sharing markets, service providers’ service quality is uneven [8], and consumers are unaware of this. As a result, there is information asymmetry between service providers and consumers, which makes it difficult for consumers to obtain accurate quality information before booking services [1]. Some drivers of ride-hailing platforms such as Uber and Didi may not be familiar with the roads or have detour issues. For example, some hosts on the house-sharing platforms of Booking.com and Airbnb may falsely advertise their houses’ location and facilities, which may lead to dissatisfaction among consumers and potential security risks [9]. Some consumers will be reluctant to use P2P sharing services due to concerns about the quality of P2P services. Low-quality services have reduced the attractiveness of P2P services to consumers, which will further affect the revenue of the entire P2P service-sharing market [10].
Since consumers cannot access services before renting, they feel great uncertainty about service quality when booking services through online platforms [11]. Therefore, they often use consumers’ online reviews as a reliable source of information [12]. It is worth noting that online consumer reviews are generated by consumers when they trade and interact with platform enterprises for multiple periods. Online consumer reviews can alleviate consumers’ concerns about quality uncertainty or product suitability, which significantly affects consumers’ decision making and has become the focus of extensive research in recent years [13–16]. According to a survey by Bright Local in 2019, 82% of online consumers read online reviews before making a purchase decision [17]. This survey indicates that consumers will refer to other people’s experiences in online reviews to help them make rental decisions [18]. In fact, the existence of a large number of online reviews on Airbnb has become one of the main factors for its success. In the case of online consumer reviews, platforms and service providers should not only consider how the review information affects consumers but also consider its impact on them. Moreover, platforms and service providers usually cannot control the effect of review information on consumers. From the platform’s perspective, the effect of the online consumer review information on the platform profit has become significant. Therefore, it is worth exploring how online consumer reviews affect the platform’s decisions.
Pricing decisions, as one of the most critical decisions for a platform, play a decisive role in creating profits for a platform. The platform influences the interaction between service providers and consumers by selecting the pricing policy. In practice, the platforms adopt different pricing policies, and we observe two types of policies: service provider pricing and platform pricing. Under the platform pricing policy, a platform sets service prices to maximize its profits. For example, Uber and Lyft set service prices to match passengers and drivers. Under the service provider pricing policy, the platform has no pricing power and service providers set the service price. For example, hosts on Airbnb, TaskRabbit, and Thumbtack set the service price. The platform generates revenue by taking commission fees from each transaction. In the service-sharing market, it is difficult for service providers to determine the price due to the uncertainty of demand and competition. For example, landlords on Airbnb are inefficient in setting prices for their services to maximize profits [19]. The service price has a considerable impact on the platform’s profit. Higher service prices will lead to fewer transactions but higher profit margins, while lower prices may increase the number of transactions but erode profits [20]. At present, it is not clear which pricing policy is more beneficial to the platform.
Based on the above practical background, the strategic interaction between online review information disclosure and pricing decisions is complex. Online review information affects consumers’ willingness to pay, and the service price limits the demand of consumers to join the platform. Due to the interaction between online review information and platform pricing decisions, in which pricing policy can be profitable for a platform to choose, it is necessary to conduct in-depth research. Therefore, this study fills the above gap by answering the following questions:
(1) How do online consumer reviews affect the selection of the pricing policy for a sharing platform?
(2) Can a sharing platform and service providers benefit from online reviews?
(3) How do online consumer reviews affect the profits, consumer surplus, and social welfare?
This paper studies the above questions from the perspective of platform operation management to provide reference and theoretical support for the operational decision making of the sharing platform. To solve the above problems, we build a game theory model. In the model, we consider a platform service supply chain composed of a high-quality service provider, a low-quality service provider, a platform, and consumers. There are two pricing policies for the platform: service provider pricing and platform pricing. Online consumer reviews affect consumers’ rental choices. First, the profit-maximizing models of the platform and two service providers under each pricing policy are constructed, and the optimal service prices are obtained by solving the models. Then, through the comparative analysis of service provider profits, platform profits, consumer surplus, and social welfare under the two policies, this paper discusses which pricing policy is more beneficial for the platform and the service providers. Further, three extended studies are provided. The first is to consider that a platform or two service providers manipulate online reviews, the second is to consider that commission rates are endogenous, and the third is to consider the effects of the number of online reviews.
The main contributions of this study lie in three aspects. First, this paper investigates the pricing policy selection of a service-sharing platform considering online consumer reviews. This paper also examines how online consumer reviews affect market equilibrium, that is, the service price, market share, and profits. As far as we know, this has not been explored in the existing research. Therefore, this study makes up for the limitations of existing studies that only focus on the pricing policy selection of one platform [19, 21]. Second, this paper not only obtains the conditions for the optimal pricing policy of the platform but also reveals the effects of online review information on the platform profit, service provider profits, consumer surplus, and social welfare, which can provide a crucial basis for the operation decision of the platform. Third, unlike existing studies (e.g., [19, 21]), we find several new conclusions. For example, under the platform pricing policy, the platform can gain large profits, but under certain conditions, it may damage consumer surplus and social welfare.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the relevant literature. Section 3 describes the problem. Section 4 gives the model settings and optimal results under the two policies. Next, in Section 5, we compare the service prices, profits, consumer surplus, and social welfare under the two policies. Section 6 gives three extended studies. Section 7 summarizes this paper’s conclusions and management insights and gives the future research. All proofs are provided in the Appendix.
2. Literature Review
This study is closely related to two streams of the literature: the pricing policy of a supply chain and online consumer reviews.
The first stream of the literature studies the pricing policy of a supply chain, and we can see that some scholars have done some research work. Feng et al. [22] studied pricing strategies for new products by using different choice behaviors of two types of consumers. Liu et al. [23] considered a problem of two-period pricing and strategy choice for a supply chain consisting of a supplier and a retailer in the presence of uncertain basic market demand and uncertain product review. Wu et al. [24] showed that when product competition is strong and no consumer switching behavior occurs, competing retailers always adopt symmetric sampling strategies to allow consumers to resolve such uncertainty before purchase. Moreover, the most relevant to our work is the pricing policy of P2P service-sharing platforms. Cachon et al. [25] studied the pricing mechanism of a service-sharing platform: fixed wage, fixed price, and peak pricing. They found that the peak pricing strategy benefits service providers and consumers under certain conditions. Liu et al. [3] studied the effects of the matching ability, the scale of service providers, and the differentiated services on the platform’s service prices and wages. Taylor [26] studied how a service platform sets the service price charged to consumers and the wage paid to service providers. The results showed that with the increase in delay sensitivity, the service price will increase while the salary will decrease. Benjaafar et al. [27] studied how a sharing platform determines the service price and the wage. They found that the low wage will damage the service provider surplus. Gibbs et al. [28] used the feature pricing model to study the impacts of multiple variables on Airbnb’s service price. They indicated that the room characteristics, location, and host characteristics significantly affect the service price. Zhao et al. [29] studied the differentiated pricing strategy of a ride-sharing platform and pointed out the specific conditions for adopting each strategy. Additionally, most relevant to our research, Pavlov and Berman [19] studied the pricing mechanism of a P2P platform in the sharing economy: platform pricing and service provider pricing. They showed that the platform pricing mechanism is not always optimal. Unlike the above research, this paper considers a platform service supply chain composed of a high-quality service provider, a low-quality service provider, and a service-sharing platform. The effect of online reviews on platform pricing policy selection is studied. For the two policies of a platform: service provider pricing and platform pricing, we discuss which pricing policy is beneficial for the platform. This study fills the gaps of existing research.
The second stream of the literature studies online consumer reviews. For this aspect of research, online consumer reviews are regarded as information tools to reveal the quality or applicability of products. Kwark et al. [14] pointed out that providing product information with different dimensions may soften or intensify upstream competition. Liu et al. [15] focused on online reviews and sales information. They showed that the two types of information mutually promote the company’s profit. Chen et al. [30] studied the impact of online consumer review information on the platform profit. They found that when the consumer heterogeneity is low, providing online consumer review information will intensify the competition of service providers and damage the platform profit. Moreover, Xiao et al. [31] showed that only when online consumer reviews are sufficiently positive do online consumer reviews raise overall prices and profits for manufacturers and the entire supply chain, which is always harmful to retailers. Huang et al. [32] explored whether and when a company should adopt reviews from a supply chain perspective. Ren et al. [33] studied the impact of online reviews on the pricing of the home-sharing platform Airbnb, and they found that the number of online reviews positively correlates with the service price. Wang and Nicolau [34] analyzed the determinants of the service price of the home-sharing platform in the sharing economy. They found that the higher the average score of customers, the higher the service price. Moreover, the number of online reviews negatively affects the service price. It should be pointed out that one of the most significant features of service-sharing platforms is online review information, which is rarely studied in existing research. Unlike the above studies, we investigate the pricing policy selection of a P2P service-sharing platform based on online consumer reviews. We also explore the impacts of different pricing policies on the platform profit, service provider profits, consumer surplus, and social welfare. Additionally, in the extended studies, we also analyze the situation in which online reviews are manipulated and the impacts of the number of online reviews. This study makes up for the limitations of the existing studies. Table 1 shows how our study differs from the most relevant literature.
Table 1
The differences between our study and relevant literature.
Zhang et al. [35] | Feng et al. [22] | Liu et al. [23] | Pavlov and Berman [19] | Chi et al. [1] | This study | |
Pricing decisions | ✓ | ✓ | ✓ | ✓ | ✓ | ✓ |
Pricing policy | ✗ | ✗ | ✗ | ✓ | ✓ | ✓ |
Online reviews | ✓ | ✗ | ✓ | ✗ | ✗ | ✓ |
Differentiated service quality | ✗ | ✗ | ✗ | ✓ | ✗ | ✓ |
Platform service supply chain | ✗ | ✓ | ✗ | ✗ | ✗ | ✓ |
3. Problem Description
This paper considers a platform service supply chain composed of a high-quality service provider, a low-quality service provider, and a service-sharing platform (hereinafter “platform”). The high-quality and low-quality service providers control many assets and provide vertically differentiated services to consumers through the platform. The platform has two pricing policies: service provider policy (hereinafter “Policy S”) and platform pricing (hereinafter “Policy C”). Under Policy S, each service provider determines the service price to maximize its profit; under Policy C, service providers deposit their service products on the platform, and the platform determines the service price to maximize its profit. Under each pricing policy, the platform shares the profit with service providers in a predetermined proportion for each transaction. Then, consumers decide whether to rent or not, and if so, whether to rent high-quality or low-quality service based on the service price. The market structure is shown in Figure 1.
[figure(s) omitted; refer to PDF]
In this paper, we focus on the impact of online review information on consumers’ rental decisions. To examine the effects of online reviews on pricing decisions and profits, we only consider the stable state of online reviews that have accumulated on the platform [36]. Each consumer gets the same information from online reviews, which can be positive or negative. This assumption can be used in the research of online reviews. Further, in reality, each service provider has the motivation to make online review information beneficial to it, or the platform should control misleading information to improve consumer surplus. Then, we consider the situation for manipulating online reviews in extended studies. Additionally, referring to [37], we first assume that the commission rate is exogenous and then consider the situation where the commission rate is endogenous in the extended studies.
In this paper,
Table 2
Summary of notations.
Symbol | Definitions |
Decision variable | |
The service price | |
Parameter | |
The service quality | |
Consumers’ valuation of services, | |
The commission rate for service providers | |
Information disclosed by online consumer reviews (hereinafter “review information”), | |
The weight of online consumer reviews in service evaluation | |
The demand | |
The service provider profit | |
Platform profit | |
Consumer surplus | |
Social welfare |
4. Models
The service quality of the two service providers is
This linear demand model has also been widely used and proved in the existing research. The difference is that to make it easier to get the impact of online reviews, we only consider the situation where the demands of both service providers are non-negative. That is, we have the following inequality constraint:
Next, we will consider the service provider pricing and the platform pricing, respectively. For the convenience of analysis, we first assume that the commission rate is exogenous. Then, Section 6.2 analyzes the situation where the commission rate is endogenous.
4.1. Service Provider Pricing
When the platform adopts Policy S, service providers provide services to consumers. The high-quality and low-quality service providers determine their own service prices, respectively. For each transaction, the platform will charge a predetermined commission from each transaction.
Under Policy S, the profits of the high-quality and the low-quality service providers and the platform profit are as follows:
We can obtain the following lemma by solving equations (3) and (4).
Lemma 1.
Under Policy S, the optimal price of the high-quality service is
From Lemma 1 and equations (1)–(5), the demand and profit of the high-quality service provider are
From Lemma 1, we can find that the optimal results of Policy S depend not only on
Corollary 2.
Under Policy S, the impacts of main parameters on the optimal results are shown in Table 3.
Corollary 2 shows that the more the information disclosed by online reviews is (hereinafter “online review information”), the higher the service price
The following corollary can be obtained by analyzing the service prices, demands, and profits under Policy S.
Table 3
The impacts of key parameters on the optimal results under Policy S.
If | If | If | If | If |
Corollary 3.
If
Corollary 3 gives the conditions for the coexistence of two competing service providers (
Therefore, positive or negative online reviews can encourage consumers to purchase services, and negative online reviews may not harm service providers. Sufficiently negative online reviews will reduce the profits of low-quality service providers. Specifically, service providers may gain higher profits when online review information exceeds a threshold. For example, house-sharing platforms such as Airbnb will display online reviews for each service, and consumers can learn more information by reading the comment text or images.
Corollary 4.
(i)
Corollary 4 shows that the online review information (or the weight of online reviews) has less impact on the price, demand, and the high-quality service provider profit than on the price, demand, and profit of the low-quality service provider profit. That is, the low-quality service provider is more sensitive to changes in online review information (or the weight of online reviews). These results show that service providers can benefit more from an increase in online review information (or the weight of online reviews).
In other words, service providers can take measures (such as giving small gifts and coupons) to motivate consumers to provide more comprehensive online reviews. Specifically, the increase in online review information may increase service providers’ profits and attract many consumers to purchase services. Therefore, service providers can promote transactions between themselves and consumers by providing high-quality services to consumers.
Referring to [38], consumer surplus can be expressed as
Social welfare can be expressed as
Further, we can obtain the following corollary.
Corollary 5.
(i)
Corollary 5 (i) shows that the impacts of online reviews on consumer surplus and social welfare are complex. That is, with the increase of online review information, both consumer surplus and social welfare will increase. This is because online reviews slow down the competition between the two service providers. With the increase of online review information, consumers can buy services at a lower mismatch cost. The matching between consumers’ preferences and services may improve the efficiency of the online market, which in turn will increase consumer surplus and social welfare.
Corollary 5 (ii) indicates that consumer surplus and social welfare first decrease and then increase in the weight of online reviews when the online review information is small. This is because when online review information is small, consumers can purchase the service at a lower price and may incur mismatching costs. Therefore, consumer surplus and social welfare will decrease, and social welfare will also decrease.
This finding effectively explains why some house-sharing platforms, such as Airbnb and HomeAway, offer landlords smart pricing tools. Even if the platform’s profit declines, shared services will become increasingly popular because of consumer surplus and social welfare improvement.
4.2. Platform Pricing
Under Policy C, the platform determines both high-quality and low-quality service prices to maximize its profit. The platform collects a predetermined commission fee from each transaction. We construct the profit-maximizing model of the platform as
Furthermore, the profit function of the high-quality service provider is
By solving equation (8), Lemma 6 can be obtained.
Lemma 6.
Under Policy C, the optimal price of the high-quality service is
Further, the demand and the profit of the high-quality service provider are
Corollary 7.
Under Policy C, the impacts of key parameters on the optimal results are shown in Table 4.
Corollary 7 shows that the more the online review information is (i.e.,
We obtain the following corollaries by analyzing the service price, the demand, and the profit under Policy C.
Table 4
Impacts of key parameters on the optimal results under Policy C.
If | If | If | If |
Corollary 8.
If
Corollary 8 gives the conditions for the coexistence of two service providers (i.e.,
Corollary 9.
(i)
From Corollary 9, we can find that the impact of online review information on the price and demand of the high-quality service is equal to the impact on the price and demand of the low-quality service. In contrast, the impact of online review information on the profit of the high-quality service provider is less than the impact on the profit of the low-quality service provider. This is because, under Policy C, the platform determines the high-quality and low-quality service prices to maximize its profit while there is no competition between providers. Therefore, the impact of online review information on the price and demand of the high-quality and the low-quality services remains unchanged. The results and potential mechanisms of Corollary 9 (ii) are consistent with Corollary 4 (ii), and we omitted more details here.
Similar to Policy S, consumer surplus can be expressed as
Social welfare is the sum of the profits of two service providers, the platform profit, and consumer surplus. Further, Social welfare can be expressed as
Corollary 10.
(i)
Corollary 10 indicates that consumer surplus and social welfare will increase with the increase of online review information. Moreover, when there is less online review information, consumer surplus and social welfare first decrease and then increase as the weight of online reviews increases. This finding is consistent with the result of Corollary 5. When online review information is small, it is not beneficial for consumer surplus and social welfare. When the online review information is sufficient and positive, online reviews benefit consumer surplus and social welfare. Therefore, the platform can encourage consumers to provide more online reviews by adopting incentive measures (such as coupons) to improve consumer surplus and social welfare.
5. Analysis and Discussion
In this section, by comparing the platform profits, the service provider profits, consumer surpluses, and social welfare under Policies S and C, we obtain the following propositions. We also use numerical analysis to visualize our results and obtain some new findings. Referring to [35], the values of some parameters are set to
Proposition 11.
(i)
Proposition 11 shows that the demand of the high-quality (low-quality) service provider under Policy S is higher than that under Policy C, and the price of the high-quality (low-quality) service provider under Policy S is lower than that under Policy C. This is because, under Policy S, when the high-quality service provider and the low-quality service provider compete in price, the demand of both service providers is high. Policy S helps market segmentation to ease the competition between service providers. Under Policy S, the demand is higher when service providers compete in price. This result is intuitive. We usually believe that when a platform adopts Policy C, it weakens competition among service providers and increases the service prices.
Figures 2 and 3 visually display the above results and demonstrate the impact of the weight of online reviews on platform pricing decisions and consumer demand.
From Figures 2 and 3, we can see that regardless of whether the platform adopts Policy S or C, as consumers increase their weight on online reviews, they are more willing to purchase services. These findings can provide a reference for the pricing decisions of platforms and service providers. The platforms and service providers can make pricing decisions to attract more potential consumers.
[figure(s) omitted; refer to PDF]
Proposition 12.
(i) If
Proposition 12 indicates that when the online review information is small, the high-quality service provider profit under Policy C is higher than that under Policy S. On the contrary, the low-quality service provider gains more profit under Policy S. When the online review information is moderate, Policy C benefits the high-quality and the low-quality service providers. When the online review information is large, the high-quality service provider profit under Policy S is higher than that under Policy C, while the low-quality service provider profit is high. That is, when the online review information is small, the high-quality service provider is more willing to determine the service price by the platform. In contrast, the low-quality service provider is more inclined to have pricing power. When the online review information is large, the high-quality service provider is more willing to decide the service price, while the low-quality service provider is more willing to determine the price by the platform. This is because, when the online review information is small, the low-quality service provider can attract consumers by lowering the service price. With the increase of the online review information, it is beneficial to the low-quality service provider, but it will damage the high-quality service provider profit. Figure 4 visualizes the results of Proposition 12.
We also analyze the effects of the weight of online reviews and the commission rate on the profits of high-quality and low-quality service providers, as shown in Figures 5 and 6. We can see from Figure 5 that under Policy S or C, the profit of the high-quality service provider decreases in the weight. Under Policy S, the profit of the low-quality service provider increases in the weight. Under Policy C, the profit of the low-quality service provider decreases first and then increases in the weight. We can see from Figure 6 that the commission rate negatively affects the profits of the high-quality and low-quality service providers.
[figure(s) omitted; refer to PDF]
Proposition 13.
Proposition 13 indicates that the platform profit under Policy C is higher than that under Policy S. This is because, under Policy C, platform pricing weakens the competition between the two service providers and increases the service price. If the quality of the service provider on the platform is uncertain and when the online review information is negative, the platform should transfer the pricing power to the service provider, which is beneficial to the platform.
This result has important management implications for the P2P service-sharing industry. This indicates that the platform has greater flexibility in influencing the number of consumers. For example, the online review system established by the platform promotes interaction between both parties and further encourages more consumers to purchase services. This finding validates Airbnb’s approach in reality. Airbnb is a well-run platform in an emerging industry, but its landlords (i.e., service providers) have lower efficiency in setting prices to maximize profits. Therefore, Airbnb launched a smart pricing tool based on internal algorithms in 2015. If landlords can use the platform’s pricing tools appropriately, they can earn 40% more profits. From Proposition 12 and 13, we find that regardless of the pricing policy adopted by the platform, service quality and online review information are important factors affecting the rapid development of the platform. Figure 7 visualizes the results of Proposition 13. Moreover, we can see from Figure 7 that under Policy S or C, platform profit decreases in the weight and increases in the commission rate.
[figure(s) omitted; refer to PDF]
Proposition 14.
(i) If
Proposition 14 (i) indicates that when the online review information is small (i.e.,
We use Figures 8 and 9 to illustrate the results of Proposition 14. We can also see from Figures 8 and 9 that under Policy S, the profits and demand of the high-quality and low-quality service providers increase in the online review information, respectively. Under Policy C, the profit and demand of low-quality service providers increase in the online review information, and the profit of high-quality service providers increases in the online review information, while the demand of the high-quality service provider is not affected by the online review information.
[figure(s) omitted; refer to PDF]
Proposition 15.
(i)
Proposition 15 (i) indicates that consumer surplus under Policy S is higher. This is because, under Policy S, service providers compete in price, the consumer demand is higher, and consumers can purchase services at lower prices. This is beneficial for consumers but disadvantageous for service providers. Under Policy C, the platform replaces the service provider to determine the price. If the service price is high, the total demand will be lower than that under Policy S. Therefore, consumer surplus will increase under Policy S.
Proposition 15 (ii) indicates that social welfare under Policy S is also higher. This is because Policy S may increase the profits of high-quality and low-quality service providers and the platform profit at the expense of sacrificing consumer surplus. Moreover, online review information provides a better match between consumers and services and reduces the mismatch cost in the entire market. As a result, social welfare has increased. This finding can also explain why some house-sharing platforms (such as Airbnb, Roomorama, and Tujia) are determined by service providers for prices.
We use Figure 10 to visualize the results of Proposition 15 and analyze the impact of the weight of online reviews on consumer surplus and social welfare. From Figure 10, we can see that as the weight of online reviews increases, consumer surplus and social welfare also increase under each pricing policy. This is because the increase in the weight of online reviews under each pricing policy leads to a decrease in service prices and platform profits, which in turn benefits consumers and increases social welfare. In this situation, consumers care more about online review information, and therefore, platforms can increase consumer surplus and social welfare by incentivizing consumers to provide more reviews.
The results of Proposition 15 and Figure 10 can provide some reference for the decision making of the platform. The platform needs to pay attention to the online review information to maximize its profit without decreasing consumer surplus and the profits of two service providers. Moreover, the platform needs to make a trade-off between attracting more consumers and making more profit.
[figure(s) omitted; refer to PDF]
6. Extensions
In this section, three extended studies are given to check the robustness of the above results and obtain some new conclusions. First, we study how service providers and platforms manipulate online reviews. Second, we analyze the case where the commission rate is endogenous. Third, we analyze the effect of the number of online reviews.
6.1. Online Review Manipulation
Online review information affects the surpluses of service providers and consumers. According to the conclusion of Section 5, if the online review information is small or negative, the low-quality service provider will be driven out of the market. It is assumed that the service providers have the motivation to make the online review information beneficial to themselves. Alternatively, the platform should manipulate misleading information to improve consumer surplus. Next, referring to [39], we analyze the situation that two service providers manipulate online reviews under Policy S, and the platform manipulates online reviews under Policy C.
We regard
Under Policy S, we can construct the profit functions of two service providers as follows:
When the manipulation cost coefficient is sufficiently large, i.e.,
Under Policy C, the platform’s profit function can be expressed as
When the manipulation cost coefficient is sufficiently large, i.e.,
We obtain the following proposition by comparing the optimal manipulation efforts under the two policies.
Proposition 16.
(i)
Proposition 16 points out that under Policy S, the low-quality service provider will pay more manipulation efforts to attract more consumers, which makes online reviews disclose more favorable information. Under Policy C, the platform makes the same manipulation efforts for the two services. That is, the platform can control misleading information, increase the matching degree between consumers and services, and improve consumer surplus. With the increase of the manipulation cost, the profits of the platform and the high-quality service provider will decrease, while the low-quality service provider can obtain more profit. That is, the platform manipulates online reviews, which are more beneficial to low-quality service providers. Therefore, manipulating online reviews is a useful tool that can reduce the credibility of online reviews. Without online reviews, consumers will face great uncertainty about the service. Online reviews significantly reduce the uncertainty between service providers and consumers. We find that reducing uncertainty is not always beneficial for platforms.
6.2. Endogenous Commission Rate
In this subsection, referring to [37], we regard the commission rate (i.e., k) as an endogenous variable, which will be affected by the external selection of service providers.
We define the reservation profit of the service provider i as
Since the service quality of the high-quality service provider is larger than that of the low-quality service provider, we assume that
Under Policy S, the profit functions of the high-quality service provider and the low-quality service provider are shown in equation (3) and (4), respectively. The profit function needs to satisfy that the profit of the high-quality and low-quality service providers should not be less than their reservation profits. By solving the profit functions (see Appendix), we obtain the optimal commission rate as follows:
Under Policy C, the profit function of the platform is shown in equation (8), where k is an endogenous variable. Similarly, the profit function also needs to satisfy that the profits of the high-quality and low-quality service providers should not be less than their reservation profits. By solving the profit function, we can obtain the optimal commission rate as follows:
Through analysis, we can find that, first, under Policy S, the larger the online review information or the weight of online reviews, the higher the commission rate. Second, under Policy C, with the increase of the online review information, the commission rate is high. Additionally, the commission rate is also related to the weight of online reviews. When
6.3. The Effects of the Number of Online Reviews
The number of online reviews is also one of the most important characteristics that affect consumers’ willingness to purchase [40]. Online reviews provide consumers with more information about services when searching for them. 79% of consumers follow the number of online reviews. Most consumers believe that the number of online reviews is a sign of product popularity. Next, we analyze the impact of the number of online reviews on platform pricing policy selection and optimal pricing decisions.
Similar to Section 3, the service qualities of the two service providers are
Under Policy S, the profit-maximizing models of the high-quality and the low-quality service providers are
Lemma 17.
Under Policy S, the optimal price of the high-quality service is
From Lemma 17, we can obtain the demand of the profit of the high-quality service provider as
Under Policy C, the profit-maximizing model of the platform is
Lemma 18.
Under Policy C, the optimal price of the high-quality service is
Furthermore, we can obtain the demands of the high-quality and the low-quality service as
By comparing the profits of service providers and platform profit under two pricing policies, we can obtain the following proposition. We also use numerical analysis to visualize our findings.
Proposition 19.
(i) If
Proposition 19 indicates that when the sensitivity coefficient (i.e.,
[figure(s) omitted; refer to PDF]
Proposition 20.
Proposition 20 indicates that the platform profit under Policy S is higher than that under Policy C. This is because the competition between two service providers is weakened and service prices are increased. This finding is consistent with the result of Proposition 13. Therefore, the main results and management implications we obtained are still robust. Moreover, Figure 12 visualizes the result of Proposition 20. We can also see from Figure 12 that the platform profit increases in the sensitivity coefficient (i.e.,
[figure(s) omitted; refer to PDF]
7. Conclusions
This paper studies the pricing policy selection of a service-sharing platform based on online consumer reviews. A platform service supply chain composed of a high-quality service provider, a low-quality service provider, and a sharing platform is considered. For the two pricing policies of the platform: service provider pricing and platform pricing, we give the optimal results for each policy. This paper also examines the impacts of online consumer reviews on the pricing strategies, profits, consumer surplus, and social welfare under different pricing policies. We also give three extended studies. The first is to consider the situation of manipulating online reviews, the second is to consider the situation where the commission rate is endogenous, and the third is to consider the effect of the number of online reviews on the platform’s pricing policy selection.
The important findings of this study are summarized below. First, under each pricing policy, the impact of online review information on the high-quality service provider profit is always smaller than the low-quality service provider profit. The low-quality service provider is more sensitive to changes in online review information. With the increase of online review information, consumer surplus and social welfare will increase. Second, when the online review information is small, the high-quality service provider obtains more profits under Policy C, while the low-quality service provider gets more profits under Policy S. When the online review information is moderate, both the high-quality the low-quality service providers are profitable under Policy C. When the online review information is large, the high-quality service provider obtains more profits under Policy S, while the low-quality service provider gets more profits under Policy C. Third, under Policy C, the price of high-quality (low-quality) service provider is high, and the demand is small. Moreover, the platform profit is large, while the consumer surplus and social welfare are small.
Additionally, we also discuss the model assumptions extensively. First, we analyze the situation where the service providers or the platform manipulates online reviews. That is, consumers get different review information from online reviews of the high-quality and the low-quality services. We find that under Policy S, a low-quality service provider will manipulate more to attract more consumers, which can make online reviews show more favorable information. Under Policy C, the platform makes the same manipulation effort for both services, that is, the platform will control misleading information. Second, under the situation of endogenous commission rate, we find that under Policy C, the larger the weight of online reviews or online review information, the higher the commission rate. Under Policy C, with the increase of online review information, the commission rate will also increase. The commission rate decreases first and then increases with the increase of online review information. Moreover, the commission rate under Policy S is smaller than that under Policy C. Third, we consider the effect of the number of online reviews on the profits of platforms and service providers. The results show that when the sensitivity coefficient is moderate, it is advantageous for both high-quality and low-quality service providers under Policy S. That is, both service providers benefit from an increase in the number of online reviews.
This study also provides some management implications for service providers and P2P service platforms. First, the platform adopts various technologies to reduce consumers’ uncertainty and match them with their favorite services. For example, the platform has developed the online review systems and the service recommendation systems. Two service providers and platforms can benefit from online reviews, and platforms should encourage consumers to provide online reviews. For example, the platform can provide consumers with some templates to guide them to give online review information. Second, when the platform adopts the service provider pricing, it is beneficial to consumers, and more consumers join the platform. Social welfare brought by the service provider pricing is higher than the platform pricing. Therefore, a platform in the early stage of development should let service providers price if it is willing to sacrifice some profits for a large market share. In contrast, a mature platform should determine the service price according to profit maximization. In reality, Airbnb’s pricing strategy verifies this finding. When Airbnb was first established, the landlords determined the price. Later, they launched a price suggestion service. The introduction of this intelligent pricing brings Airbnb closer to setting the price by the platform.
Future research can be carried out in two aspects. First, this paper considers that the platform can only choose one pricing policy. It will be an interesting question if the platform can adopt two pricing policies simultaneously. Second, there is competition among some P2P service-sharing platforms in the market. Therefore, it is interesting to explore the decision making of multiple platforms in a competitive environment.
Authors’ Contributions
Jing Tian was responsible for review and editing. Xiaodong Wang was responsible for writing, methodology, visualization, formal analysis, and investigation. Jinhuan Meng was responsible for methodology and review and editing. Pengfei Ma was responsible for supervision, conceptualization, and review and editing.
Acknowledgments
It is gratefully acknowledged that this study was supported by Department of Management Engineering, Inner Mongolia Vocational and Technical College of Communications, Chifeng, Inner Mongolia, China.
A. Proof of Lemma 1
Substituting equations (1) and (2) into equations (3) and (4), equations (3) and (4) can be further expressed as
According to equation (A.1), the first-order and the second-order conditions of equation (A.1) with
According to equation (A.2), the first-order and the second-order conditions of equation (A.2) with
Obviously,
Hence, Lemma 1 holds.
B. Proof of Corollary 2
The first conditions of
The first conditions of
The proof process of the remaining corollaries is similar to that of Corollary 2, which is not discussed here.
C. Proof of Lemma 6
Substituting equations (1) and (2) into equation (8), equation (8) can be further expressed as
For equation (C.1), we can obtain the first-order conditions for
Furthermore, we can obtain
Obviously,
Hence, Lemma 6 holds.
D. Proof of Proposition 11
(i) From Lemmas 1 and 6, we can obtain
(ii) From Lemmas 1 and 6, we can obtain
Hence, Proposition 11 holds.
The proof process of the remaining propositions is similar to that of Proposition 11, which is not discussed here.
E. Proof in Section 6.2
Under Policy S, from the results in Section 4.1, we can obtain
The profit-maximizing model of the platform is
Under Policy C, from the results in Section 4.2, we can obtain
The profit-maximizing model for the platform is
It is easy to obtain
F. Proof of Lemma 17
The profit-maximizing models of two service providers can be further expressed as
The second-order condition of equation (F.1) with
Hence, Lemma 17 holds.
G. Proof of Lemma 18
The profit-maximizing model of the platform can be further expressed as
From equation (G.1), we can obtain the first-order conditions for
Furthermore, we can obtain
Obviously,
Hence, Lemma 18 holds.
[1] X. Chi, Z. P. Fan, X. Wang, "The entry quality threshold setting and commission rate contract selection of a peer-to-peer service sharing platform," 2021. https://www.emerald.com/insight/content/doi/10.1108/K-02-2022-0248/full/html
[2] V. Kamble, "Revenue management on an on-demand service platform," Operations Research Letters, vol. 47 no. 5, pp. 377-385, DOI: 10.1016/j.orl.2019.07.001, 2019.
[3] W. Liu, X. Yan, W. Wei, D. Xie, "Pricing decisions for service platform with provider’s threshold participating quantity, value-added service and matching ability," Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, vol. 122, pp. 410-432, DOI: 10.1016/j.tre.2018.12.020, 2019.
[4] T. M. Choi, Y. He, "Peer-to-peer collaborative consumption for fashion products in the sharing economy: platform operations," Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, vol. 126, pp. 49-65, DOI: 10.1016/j.tre.2019.03.016, 2019.
[5] V. Kumar, A. Lahiri, O. Dogan, "A strategic framework for a profitable business model in the sharing economy," Industrial Marketing Management, vol. 69, pp. 147-160, DOI: 10.1016/j.indmarman.2017.08.021, 2018.
[6] K. Govindan, K. M. Shankar, D. Kannan, "Achieving sustainable development goals through identifying and analyzing barriers to industrial sharing economy: Achieving sustainable development goals through identifying and analyzing barriers to industrial sharing economy: A framework development framework development," International Journal of Production Economics, vol. 227,DOI: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2019.107575, 2020.
[7] X. Xu, "How do consumers in the sharing economy value sharing? Evidence from online reviews," Decision Support Systems, vol. 128,DOI: 10.1016/j.dss.2019.113162, 2020.
[8] B. Gao, M. Zhu, S. Liu, M. Jiang, "Different voices between Airbnb and hotel customers: an integrated analysis of online reviews using structural topic model," Journal of Hospitality and Tourism Management, vol. 51, pp. 119-131, DOI: 10.1016/j.jhtm.2022.03.004, 2022.
[9] W. Wei, W. Liu, O. Tang, C. Dong, "CSR investment for a two-sided platform: network externality and risk aversion," European Journal of Operational Research, vol. 307 no. 2, pp. 694-712, DOI: 10.1016/j.ejor.2022.08.048, 2023.
[10] R. Li, Y. Q. Li, W. Q. Ruan, S. N. Zhang, M. Y. Wang, "Sentiment mining of online reviews of peer-to-peer accommodations: Sentiment mining of online reviews of peer-to-peer accommodations: Customer emotional heterogeneity and its influencing factorsustomer emotional heterogeneity and its influencing factors," Tourism Management, vol. 96,DOI: 10.1016/j.tourman.2022.104704, 2023.
[11] D. Farrell, F. Greig, "Paychecks, paydays, and the online platform economy," Proceedings. Annual Conference on Taxation and Minutes of the Annual Meeting of the National Tax Association, vol. 109, 2016.
[12] X. Xu, S. Zeng, Y. He, "The impact of information disclosure on consumer purchase behavior on sharing economy platform Airbnb," International Journal of Production Economics, vol. 231,DOI: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2020.107846, 2021.
[13] Y. Jiang, H. Guo, "Design of consumer review systems and product pricing," Information Systems Research, vol. 26 no. 4, pp. 714-730, DOI: 10.1287/isre.2015.0594, 2015.
[14] Y. Kwark, J. Chen, S. Raghunathan, "Online product reviews: implications for retailers and competing manufacturers," Information Systems Research, vol. 25 no. 1, pp. 93-110, DOI: 10.1287/isre.2013.0511, 2014.
[15] Y. Liu, J. Feng, X. Liao, "When online reviews meet sales volume information: is more or accurate information always better?," Information Systems Research, vol. 28 no. 4, pp. 723-743, DOI: 10.1287/isre.2017.0715, 2017.
[16] M. Siering, A. V. Deokar, C. Janze, "Disentangling consumer recommendations: explaining and predicting airline recommendations based on online reviews," Decision Support Systems, vol. 107, pp. 52-63, DOI: 10.1016/j.dss.2018.01.002, 2018.
[17] S. Lee, S. Lee, H. Baek, "Does the dispersion of online review ratings affect review helpfulness," Computers in Human Behavior, vol. 117,DOI: 10.1016/j.chb.2020.106670, 2021.
[18] Y. Li, G. Li, G. K. Tayi, T. C. E. Cheng, "Omni-channel retailing: do offline retailers benefit from online reviews," International Journal of Production Economics, vol. 218, pp. 43-61, DOI: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2019.05.002, 2019.
[19] V. Pavlov, R. Berman, "Price manipulation in peer-to-peer markets and the sharing economy," SSRN,DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3468447, 2019.
[20] Q. Zheng, D. Ke, X. Li, "Optimal pricing strategies for Airbnb when competing with incumbents on two sides," International Journal of Hospitality Management, vol. 108,DOI: 10.1016/j.ijhm.2022.103392, 2023.
[21] L. Liang, L. Tian, J. Xie, J. Xu, W. Zhang, "Optimal pricing model of car-sharing: market pricing or platform pricing," Industrial Management and Data Systems, vol. 121 no. 3, pp. 594-612, DOI: 10.1108/imds-04-2020-0230, 2021.
[22] S. Feng, X. Hu, A. Yang, J. Liu, "Pricing strategy for new products with presales," Mathematical Problems in Engineering, vol. 2019,DOI: 10.1155/2019/1287968, 2019.
[23] Z. Liu, R. Gao, C. Zhou, N. Ma, "Two-period pricing and strategy choice for a supply chain with dual uncertain information under different profit risk levels," Computers and Industrial Engineering, vol. 136, pp. 173-186, DOI: 10.1016/j.cie.2019.07.029, 2019.
[24] L. Wu, S. Deng, X. Jiang, "Sampling and pricing strategy under competition," Omega, vol. 80, pp. 192-208, DOI: 10.1016/j.omega.2018.01.002, 2018.
[25] G. P. Cachon, K. M. Daniels, R. Lobel, "The role of surge pricing on a service platform with self-scheduling capacity," Manufacturing and Service Operations Management, vol. 19 no. 3, pp. 368-384, DOI: 10.1287/msom.2017.0618, 2017.
[26] T. A. Taylor, "On-demand service platforms," Manufacturing and Service Operations Management, vol. 20 no. 4, pp. 704-720, DOI: 10.1287/msom.2017.0678, 2018.
[27] S. Benjaafar, G. Kong, X. Li, C. Courcoubetis, "Peer-to-peer product sharing: implications for ownership, usage, and social welfare in the sharing economy," Management Science, vol. 65 no. 2, pp. 477-493, DOI: 10.1287/mnsc.2017.2970, 2019.
[28] C. Gibbs, D. Guttentag, U. Gretzel, J. Morton, A. Goodwill, "Pricing in the sharing economy: a hedonic pricing model applied to Airbnb listings," Journal of Travel and Tourism Marketing, vol. 35 no. 1, pp. 46-56, DOI: 10.1080/10548408.2017.1308292, 2018.
[29] D. Zhao, Z. Yuan, M. Chen, S. Yang, "Differential pricing strategies of ride‐sharing platforms: choosing customers or drivers," International Transactions in Operational Research, vol. 29 no. 2, pp. 1089-1131, DOI: 10.1111/itor.13045, 2022.
[30] X. Chen, G. Li, S. Li, Q. Zheng, "Should a sharing platform adopt the bilateral review system," 2020. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3724924
[31] L. Xiao, Z. S. Chen, K. Govindan, M. J. Skibniewski, "Effects of online consumer reviews on a dual-channel closed-loop supply chain with trade," IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management,DOI: 10.1109/TEM.2022.3167160, 2022.
[32] S. Huang, A. Potter, D. Eyers, Q. Li, "The influence of online review adoption on the profitability of capacitated supply chains," Omega, vol. 105,DOI: 10.1016/j.omega.2021.102501, 2021.
[33] J. Ren, V. Raghupathi, W. Raghupathi, "Effect of crowd wisdom on pricing in the asset-based sharing platform: Effect of crowd wisdom on pricing in the asset-based sharing platform: An attribute substitution perspectiven attribute substitution perspective," International Journal of Hospitality Management, vol. 94,DOI: 10.1016/j.ijhm.2021.102874, 2021.
[34] D. Wang, J. L. Nicolau, "Price determinants of sharing economy based accommodation rental: a study of listings from 33 cities on Airbnb. Com," International Journal of Hospitality Management, vol. 62, pp. 120-131, DOI: 10.1016/j.ijhm.2016.12.007, 2017.
[35] T. Zhang, G. Li, T. C. E. Cheng, K. K. Lai, "Welfare economics of review information: implications for the online selling platform owner," International Journal of Production Economics, vol. 184, pp. 69-79, DOI: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2016.10.017, 2017.
[36] X. Guan, Y. Wang, Z. Yi, Y. J. Chen, "Inducing consumer online reviews via disclosure," Production and Operations Management, vol. 29 no. 8, pp. 1956-1971, DOI: 10.1111/poms.13199, 2020.
[37] H. Zhu, M. Gumus, S. Ray, "Short-term housing rentals and corporatization of platform pricing," 2019. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3344260
[38] Y. Chen, D. Wang, K. Chen, Y. Zha, G. Bi, "Optimal pricing and availability strategy of a bike-sharing firm with time-sensitive customers," Journal of Cleaner Production, vol. 228, pp. 208-221, DOI: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.04.151, 2019.
[39] H. Cao, "Online review manipulation by asymmetrical firms: is a firm’s manipulation of online reviews always detrimental to its competitor," Information and Management, vol. 57 no. 6,DOI: 10.1016/j.im.2019.103244, 2020.
[40] H. Li, K. Yang, G. Zhang, "The impact of online reviews on pricing strategy and coordination in a two-period two-echelon supply chain," INFOR: Information Systems and Operational Research, vol. 61 no. 1,DOI: 10.1080/03155986.2022.2049154, 2023.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer
Copyright © 2023 Jing Tian et al. This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License (the “License”), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. Notwithstanding the ProQuest Terms and Conditions, you may use this content in accordance with the terms of the License. https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/
Abstract
In the operation of service-sharing platforms, online review information is crucial to attracting consumers. Considering consumers’ preference for online review information, this paper discusses the pricing policy selection for a service-sharing platform providing vertically differentiated services in sharing economy, which is worth studying. In this paper, a platform service supply chain composed of a high-quality service provider, a low-quality service provider, and a service-sharing platform is considered. For the two pricing policies of a platform: service provider pricing and platform pricing, the profit-maximizing models are constructed, and the optimal high-quality and the low-quality service prices are obtained. This paper also analyzes the effects of online review information on the profits of service providers, platform profits, consumer surplus, and social welfare under the two policies. The results show that under the platform pricing policy, the platform can gain more profits, while the surplus of consumers and service providers may decrease. When the online review information exceeds a threshold, the high-quality service provider profit under the service provider pricing policy is larger than that under the platform pricing policy. Under the platform pricing policy, the low-quality service provider can earn more profit. We also find that the low-quality service provider is more motivated to encourage consumers to provide online reviews regardless of the pricing policy.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer
Details




1 Department of Management Engineering, Inner Mongolia Vocational and Technical College of Communications, Chifeng, Inner Mongolia 024005, China
2 Development and Planning Department, CCTEG Shenyang Research Institute, Fushun, Liaoning 113112, China