1. Introduction
Innovation is the key driver of high-quality economic development [1]. In China, high-tech small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) play a pivotal role in economic innovation due to their adaptability and flexibility [2,3]. However, these firms face severe debt and equity financing constraints that hinder their innovative growth [4]. Debt financing is often limited for high-tech SMEs due to their small size and higher risk profile, and even when available, given the high capital needs, long cycles, and risks associated with innovation activities [5], creditors tend to restrict its use for innovation. Equity financing is similarly challenging [6], as many high-tech SMEs fall short of the size and profitability requirements for public listing and must instead rely on the National Equities Exchange and Quotations (NEEQ) system. The smaller scale, lower profitability, and less stringent disclosure standards of NEEQ-listed firms lead to its reputation as a "junk firm recycling station," reducing investor interest and stock liquidity, and undermining financing efficiency. Therefore, the dual pressures of difficulties in both debt and equity financing have compelled high-tech SMEs to rely more heavily on government subsidies,
Over the past few years, the government has provided continuous fiscal subsidies to support the innovation activities of high-tech SMEs and alleviate their financing constraints. However, due to the high informational costs between the government and the market [7] and the distortions in market mechanisms caused by government intervention [8], the innovation incentive effect of fiscal subsidies faces dual constraints in terms of ex-ante targeting and ex-post supervision. Specifically, subsidies often fail to be accurately allocated to genuinely innovative firms, and recipient firms frequently fall short of achieving their expected innovation outcomes [9]. This misallocation of resources ultimately distorts resource allocation. Meanwhile, substantial fiscal subsidies impose significant fiscal pressure on the government.
Strengthening the capital market’s support for SME innovation is a critical priority for the Chinese government. The key to addressing the current innovation challenges faced by high-tech SMEs lies in boosting the stock liquidity of NEEQ high-tech SMEs and improving information disclosure quality of these firms. Based on this, the Chinese government officially implemented the registration-based transfer listing system (RTLS) on June 3, 2020. Following several rounds of reforms and improvements, a direct connection mechanism was established between the NEEQ Innovation Layer and the Beijing Stock Exchange (BSE). Specifically, firms in the NEEQ Innovation Layer that meet the BSE listing standards can apply for a direct transfer, bypassing the traditional, complex review processes. Additionally, RTLS imposes stricter information disclosure requirements, compelling firms to disclose essential details, including financial data, innovation project progress, and risk factors, allowing investors to assess the true value and innovation potential of these firms more accurately. Thus, we focus on whether RTLS can enhance the stock liquidity, alleviate financing constraints of NEEQ high-tech SMEs, and thereby promote their innovation input. Meanwhile, we also examine whether RTLS can improve information disclosure standards, increase resource allocation efficiency, and thereby promote substantial innovation output for NEEQ high-tech SMEs.
To investigate the above issues, we use China’s specialized and sophisticated SMEs (characterized by specialization, refinement, distinctiveness, and innovation) listed on the NEEQ from 2016 to 2022 as the research sample, and employ a difference-in-differences (DID) model to examine the impact of RTLS on innovation input and substantial innovation output of NEEQ high-tech SMEs. We find that RTLS can increase innovation input of NEEQ hi-tech SMEs by an average of 0.4% for the treatment group. And we also find that RTLS can increase substantive innovation output of NEEQ hi-tech SMEs by an average of 8.8% for the treatment group. The above conclusions satisfy the parallel trends test and the placebo test. Subsequently, we conduct a series of robustness checks, including substituting the measurement methods of the dependent variables, performing entropy balancing, and excluding the interference of other policies, further confirming the robustness of the baseline results.
Based on the main regression results, we conduct mechanism tests. The mechanism results show that, on the one hand, RTLS can enhance the stock liquidity of NEEQ high-tech SMEs, facilitating their access to innovation funding and thereby increasing their innovation input. On the other hand, RTLS can improve the quality of information disclosure among NEEQ high-tech SMEs, enhancing resource allocation efficiency and ultimately boosting their substantive innovation output.
Furthermore, considering that varying firm characteristics and market environments may exert different influences on the main conclusions of this study, we conduct a heterogeneity analysis by dividing the main sample based on ownership type and the level of marketization. We find that the positive effects on innovation input and substantive innovation output are more pronounced in regions with higher marketization and among non-state-owned enterprises (non-SOEs).
Finally, we further examine the impact of RTLS on the innovation efficiency and dependence on fiscal subsidies to promote innovation of NEEQ high-tech SMEs. Our findings indicate that RTLS can enhance the innovation efficiency of NEEQ high-tech SMEs while reducing their reliance on fiscal subsidies to promote innovation.
Compared to existing literature, this paper offers three contributions. First, our study contributes to the existing literature on registration-based reform. Prior research has primarily focused on its impact on IPO pricing [10], capital market price discovery efficiency[11,12], stock return volatility [13], the cost of equity capital [14], and ESG greenwashing [15]. However, limited attention has been given to the effects of registration-based reform on SMEs. We address this gap by examining the impact of RTLS on the innovation activities of SMEs. By doing so, our research extends the literature on registration-based reform and provides new insights into its implications for SMEs.
Second, our research contributes to the literature on SME innovation. Prior literature has primarily examined the impact of traditional “government-led” policies on SME innovation, including government subsidy policies [16], tax incentives [17], and intellectual property protection policies [18]. However, few studies explore the effect of capital market institutional reforms on SME innovation. By adopting a capital market institutional innovation perspective, this study unveils the mechanism through which RTLS influences SME innovation, contributing to the literature by enriching the understanding of SME innovation drivers from the perspective of “market-driven” policies.
Finally, the findings of this study hold practical significance. While existing literature has thoroughly debated the effectiveness of government subsidies in corporate innovation [19–21], some research suggests that excessive government intervention can significantly hinder SME innovation [22]. From the perspective of capital market reform, we highlight the positive role of “market-driven” policies in fostering SME innovation. This provides policymakers with empirical insights and valuable policy references.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces the institutional background. Section 3 outlines the hypothesis development. Section 4 presents the research design. Section 5 reports the empirical results. Section 6 concludes the study by summarizing the findings and providing corresponding policy recommendations.
2. Institutional background
The NEEQ, BSE, and RTLS collectively form a progressive system within China’s multi-tiered capital market that serves SMEs. As an over-the-counter market, the NEEQ is a crucial component of China’s capital market, designed to facilitate financing for SMEs, particularly high-tech SMEs. The NEEQ is divided into two tiers: the Basic Tier and the Innovation Tier. The Basic Tier has relatively low entry requirements and primarily targets early-stage firms, whereas the Innovation Tier imposes stricter admission criteria, focusing on firms with higher growth potential. However, compared to main board-listed firms, NEEQ-listed firms are generally smaller in scale, exhibit innovation capabilities but face unstable profitability, and demonstrate varying levels of information disclosure quality. Consequently, the NEEQ has long struggled with issues such as low valuation, insufficient stock liquidity, and high financing costs, and has even been derisively referred to by some investors as a “dumping ground for underperforming firms.”
The BSE serves as a key segment of China’s capital market dedicated to facilitating the listing and financing of high-tech SMEs. Unlike the NEEQ, the BSE is part of China’s A-share market. It aims to deepen the reform of the NEEQ and enhance the multi-tiered capital market system. The BSE primarily accommodates high-quality firms from the NEEQ Innovation Tier that meet the eligibility criteria for board transition, providing high-tech SMEs with more efficient financing channels.
RTLS, introduced on June 3, 2020, serves as a crucial mechanism linking the NEEQ Innovation Tier with the BSE. Prior to its implementation, firms listed on the NEEQ seeking to transition to public markets were required to first delist and undergo a complex, costly, and time-consuming IPO process, posing significant challenges to achieving listed status. Through ongoing reforms, RTLS has established a direct connectivity mechanism between the NEEQ Innovation Tier and the BSE. The transfer listing process for NEEQ-listed SMEs is illustrated in Fig 1. Specifically, firms listed on the NEEQ Innovation Tier for at least one year and meeting the listing requirements for the target board can apply for listing on the BSE, with additional criteria established to assess the innovation capabilities of high-tech SMEs. Furthermore, firms that successfully list on the BSE may subsequently apply to transfer to the Shanghai or Shenzhen Stock Exchange if they meet the respective listing requirements, creating a multi-tiered, progressive pathway for listing. RTLS effectively expands financing opportunities for NEEQ high-tech SMEs, enhancing their access to capital markets.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Simultaneously, RTLS introduces specific regulations on information disclosure to mitigate information asymmetry between investors and NEEQ-listed firms and enhance resource allocation efficiency. On the one hand, RTLS mandates that firms applying for transfer listing ensure their information disclosure is truthful, accurate, and complete, and that it is relevant and comprehensible for significant investor decisions. Stock exchanges conduct multiple rounds of inquiries to verify the authenticity, accuracy, and completeness of disclosures, closely monitoring any instances of false reporting. On the other hand, RTLS assigns increased accountability to intermediary institutions, requiring sponsors and their representatives, accounting firms, law firms, and other securities service providers to oversee and ensure the quality of firms’ information disclosures.
3. Hypothesis
3.1 Based on market financing
Large firms typically rely on internal resources to support their R&D activities [23]. In contrast, SMEs, due to limited internal funding, tend to utilize established stock markets as a primary source of innovation financing [24–26]. Stock liquidity is the key indicators of capital market quality [27]. The introduction of RTLS can help address the stock liquidity challenges faced by NEEQ high-tech SMEs.
First, RTLS establishes a direct pathway for NEEQ high-tech SMEs to list on main exchanges. The criteria for transfer listing have shifted from a profit-focused approach to an emphasis on innovation and growth potential, with additional innovation requirements specifically tailored for NEEQ high-tech SMEs, thereby increasing the likelihood of listing for them.
Second, RTLS simplifies the listing process for NEEQ high-tech SMEs. By delegating review authority to the relevant exchanges and replacing substantive reviews with procedural ones, regulatory focus shifts to information disclosure. According to Wind Financial Terminal database, before the registration-based system was implemented, the average time from the initial IPO application to approval for NEEQ firms was 474 days; this period has since shortened to 227 days post-implementation. Thus, RTLS offers listing convenience to NEEQ high-tech SMEs, potentially raising their overall valuation and attracting more external investors. This, in turn, enhances stock liquidity, alleviating financing constraints and fostering innovation input among these firms. The specific theoretical framework is depicted in Fig 2. Based on the above analysis, we propose Hypothesis 1.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Hypothesis 1. RTLS can promote innovation input in NEEQ high-tech SMEs.
3.2 Based on information environment
Financial markets not only support economic activities by alleviating financing difficulties but also reduce information acquisition costs, enabling more effective project evaluation, selection, and monitoring. This, in turn, enhances resource allocation efficiency [28], which can significantly boost firms’ substantial innovation output [29]. Previously, the NEEQ’s information disclosure framework lacked standardization, resulting in high information opacity and elevated investment risks for investors [30]. Consequently, the price discovery function of the NEEQ was impaired, leading to significant resource misallocation. The information disclosure requirements under RTLS aim to improve the quality of information disclosure for NEEQ high-tech SMEs, thereby mitigating information asymmetry.
First, a key prerequisite for NEEQ high-tech SMEs to transition to listed status is the absence of false disclosures. Additionally, intermediaries effectively monitor these firms’ disclosure practices, increasing the cost of non-compliance. Second, the heightened investor attention and trading activity generated by RTLS provides external oversight for the NEEQ. Given the high entry threshold for NEEQ investors, most are institutional investors, who—according to effective monitoring theory—possess greater expertise in gathering, interpreting, and supervising information, leading to more effective corporate oversight. These institutional investors follow the “Wall Street Rule," influencing corporate governance through frequent trading, or “voting with their feet” [31]. Improved corporate governance reinforces information disclosure practices, thereby enhancing the disclosure quality of NEEQ high-tech SMEs. Improving the information environment optimizes the investment decisions and behaviors of all stakeholders [32], reducing information asymmetry between NEEQ high-tech SMEs and investors. This ultimately increases the efficiency of market-based resource allocation, making it easier for truly innovative firms to access necessary resources, thus promoting substantial innovation output in NEEQ high-tech SMEs. The specific theoretical framework is depicted in Fig 2. Based on the above analysis, we propose Hypothesis 2.
Hypothesis 2. RTLS can promote substantial innovation output in NEEQ high-tech SMEs.
4. Data and research design
4.1 Data source and sample selection
Considering that the innovation capabilities of NEEQ-listed firms vary significantly, with Specialized and Sophisticated SMEs placing greater emphasis on innovation, we choose the above firms as the subjects of our study. To exclude the impact of the 2016 NEEQ tiered system, we select the sample period from 2016 to 2022. The research sample is processed as follows: (1) excluding firms in the financial industry; (2) excluding samples with missing key indicators; (3) excluding ST firms; and (4) performing a two-sided 1% winsorization on all continuous variables. Ultimately, we obtain 3,659 observations for this study. Patent data is manually collected from Tianyancha website; government subsidy data is manually collected from the notes in annual reports; and other data is sourced from the Wind Financial Terminal and China Stock Market & Accounting Research (CSMAR) database.
4.2 Model
In selecting the treatment and control groups, we consider the current two-tier structure of the NEEQ, which includes the Basic Tier and the Innovation Tier. Compared to firms in the Basic Tier, firms in the Innovation Tier generally exhibit higher levels of corporate governance and innovation capabilities, making them the primary targets of the RTLS. Furthermore, the latest transfer listing policy stipulates that only firms that have been continuously listed on the Innovation Tier for at least one year are eligible to transfer to the BSE. Therefore, we designate the Innovation Tier as the treatment group and the Basic Tier as the control group. We design the model (1) to test Hypothesis 1 and model (2) to test Hypothesis 2.
(1)(2)
4.3 Definition of variables.
In model (1), the dependent variable is RDit+1, defined as R&D expenditure in period t + 1 divided by total assets in period t + 1. The independent variable is DIDit, which equals Treati×Postt. Treati is 1 if the firm belongs to the NEEQ Innovation Tier, and 0 otherwise. Postt is 1 for years 2020 and onwards, and 0 otherwise. θ1 measures the impact of RTLS on the innovation input of NEEQ high-tech SMEs. It serves as a focal point of this study. According to the theoretical analysis, if RTLS enhances the innovation input of NEEQ high-tech SMEs, we expect θ1 to be significantly positive. We also control for other variables (Controlsit) that may affect corporate innovation input, including firm size (Sizeit), debt-to-asset ratio (Levit), firm age (Ageit), largest shareholder ownership (Top1it), market power (Marketit), operating revenue (Salesit), per capita GDP (LnGDPit), return on equity (ROEit), board size (BOD_Sizeit), and profitability (Returnit).
In model (2), the dependent variable is Lninnoit+1, defined as the natural logarithm of the number of invention patent applications plus one. θ2 measures the impact of RTLS on the substantive innovation output of NEEQ high-tech SMEs. According to the theoretical analysis, if RTLS enhances the substantive innovation output of NEEQ high-tech SMEs, we expect θ2 to be significantly positive. All other variables are defined as in Model (1). The specific definitions of the variables are provided in Table 1.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
5. Empirical results
5.1 Summary statistics
Table 2 presents the results of the descriptive statistics in this study. The mean value of RD is 0.051, indicating that the average annual innovation input of firms accounts for approximately 5.1% of total assets during the sample period. The mean value of the original Lninno is 4.184, with a standard deviation of 7.996 (original values of invention patents before taking the logarithm), suggesting a significant variation in the number of invention patent applications across firms. The mean value of DID is 0.167, indicating that, on average, 16.7% of the total sample was affected by RTLS during the sample period.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
5.2 Baseline results
Table 3 presents the main regression results. In column (1), the DID coefficient is 0.004, which is significantly positive at the 1% level. This indicates that RTLS can enhance innovation input of NEEQ high-tech SMEs, supporting Hypothesis 1. From an economic perspective, RTLS can lead to an average increase of 0.4% in innovation input for NEEQ high-tech SMEs in the treatment group compared to those in the control group. In column (2), The coefficient of the DID is 0.088, which is significantly positive. The result indicates that RTLS can enhance substantive innovation output of NEEQ high-tech SMEs, supporting Hypothesis 2. From an economic perspective, RTLS can lead to an average increase of 8.8% in substantive innovation output for NEEQ high-tech SMEs in the treatment group compared to those in the control group.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
5.3 Parallel trend test
The parallel trends assumption is a prerequisite for the use of the DID model, which means that, prior to the implementation of RTLS, the innovation input trends of the treatment and control groups should satisfy the parallel trends assumption. Therefore, this study follows the approach of Jacobson et al. (1993) [33] and employs an event study methodology to test whether the main regression model in this paper satisfies the parallel trends assumption. The method can be expressed as follows.
(3)
This study takes the first period before RTLS implementation as the baseline. As shown in Table 4, columns (1) and (2) present the results of the parallel trends test for Hypothesis 1 and Hypothesis 2, respectively. Prior to the implementation of RTLS, the DID coefficients are not statistically significant. However, after RTLS implementation, the DID coefficients are significantly positive, indicating the positive impact of RTLS on the innovation input and substantive innovation output of NEEQ high-tech SMEs. These results suggest that the DID model used in this study satisfies the parallel trends assumption.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
5.4 Placebo tests
To prevent the influence of unobservable variables on the results, we conduct a placebo test. Following the method of Liu and Lu (2015) [34], Cai et al. (2016) [35] and Lu et al. (2022) [36], we randomly select DID from the full sample to perform the placebo test on the incentive effect of innovation input and substantive innovation output in NEEQ high-tech SMEs. Fig 3 shows the results of 1000 random samplings for Hypothesis 1 and Fig 4 presents the results of 1000 random samplings for Hypothesis 2. Panel A and Panel B show the results of the t-statistics and the DID estimation coefficients, respectively. In the placebo test, the dummy variables DID are randomly assigned, and thus, the interaction term is not expected to exert a significant effect on the dependent variable. Consequently, the regression coefficient of the interaction term in the placebo test should cluster around zero in the kernel density plot. Meeting this condition ensures that the model avoids identification bias stemming from omitted variables. In Figs 3 and 4, Both the t-statistics and DID estimation coefficients do not significantly deviate from zero, indicating that the placebo test is passed.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Notes: The placebo test results of the T-value (a) and estimator (b).
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Notes: The placebo test results of the T-value (a) and estimator (b).
5.5 Robustness tests
5.5.1 Replacing dependent variables.
First, we replace the dependent variable in Hypothesis 1. Given that the main regression has measured innovation input (RDit+1) using the ratio of R&D investment to total assets, we replace innovation input (RD it+1) with the ratio of R&D investment to operating income in the robustness check, denoted as Rd it+1. Subsequently, we re-estimate Model (1). As shown in Column (1) of Table 5, the DID estimate is significantly positive, supporting Hypothesis 1.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Next, we replace the dependent variable in Hypothesis 2. In the previous analysis, the logarithm of patent applications is used as a proxy for substantive innovation output (Lninno it+1). To reflect the proportion of substantive innovation output more comprehensively among all innovation outputs, we use the ratio of the number of invention patent applications in the subsequent period to the total number of patent applications (IRit+1) as the measure of substantive innovation output, and re-estimates Model (2). As shown in Column (2) of Table 5, the DID estimate is significantly positive, supporting Hypothesis 2. The above results demonstrate that even after substituting the measurement methods for the dependent variables, the DID coefficients still yield significantly positive results, confirming that RTLS for the NEEQ facilitates the innovation input and substantive innovation output of high-tech SMEs listed on the NEEQ.
5.5.2 Entropy balance test.
To reduce the impact of sample selection bias on the research results, this paper adopts entropy balancing, following the method outlined by Hainmueller (2012) [37]. First, we identify the characteristic variables that may introduce bias, and then seek a set of weights to ensure that the experimental and control groups are similar across all characteristics. Next, we assign higher weights to control group samples that are more like the experimental group and estimate the model using weighted regression. The regression results are presented in Columns (3) - (4) of Table 5. The DID coefficients are significantly positive, confirming Hypothesis 1 and Hypothesis 2.
5.5.3 Excluding the interference of other policies.
During the sample period, the increase in innovation input and substantive innovation output among NEEQ high-tech SMEs may be attributed to national policies supporting innovation and development of SMEs. To rule out the potential impact of these policies on our conclusions, we collect policy documents issued during the sample period, including the “Law of the People’s Republic of China on Promoting Small and Medium-sized Enterprises (revised in 2017),” the “State Council Opinions on Promoting High-Quality Development of Innovation and Entrepreneurship and Upgrading the ‘Mass Entrepreneurship and Innovation’ Initiative (Guofa [2018] No. 32),” and the “Guiding Opinions on Promoting the Healthy Development of Small and Medium-sized Enterprises” (issued in 2019). Accordingly, we conduct robustness tests on Models (1) and (2) using three subsample periods: 2017–2022, 2018–2022, and 2019–2022. The regression results, as shown in Table 6, indicate that the DID coefficient is significantly positive, suggesting that RTLS facilitates innovation input and substantive innovation output among high-tech SMEs listed on the NEEQ.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
5.6 Possible mechanisms
We propose that RTLS can promote innovation input of NEEQ high-tech SMEs by improving liquidity on NEEQ and alleviating financing constraints. Besides, RTLS can enhance those firms’ substantive innovation output by improving the quality of information disclosure. This section will test these two mechanisms.
5.6.1 Based on market financing.
Existing literature suggests that stock liquidity can reduce firms’ financing costs, thereby increasing their innovation input [38,39]. RTLS can enhance the stock liquidity of NEEQ high-tech SMEs. To test this mechanism, we examine stock liquidity indicators for those enterprises after the implementation of RTLS, including the Amihud illiquidity measure (Amihud), the number of nonzero trading days (Nonzero), trading volume (Volume), and turnover rate (TO). A higher Amihud value indicates poorer stock liquidity, while greater Nonzero, Volume, and TO values indicate stronger stock liquidity. Table 7, columns (1) - (4), present the regression results, indicating that RTLS improves the stock liquidity of NEEQ high-tech SMEs.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
5.6.2 Based on information environment.
Existing literature confirms that improvements in information disclosure quality help prompt substantive innovation activities [32]. RTLS can enhance firms’ information disclosure quality. To test this mechanism, we examine the information disclosure quality of NEEQ high-tech SMEs after the implementation of RTLS, using real earnings management (REM) and earnings opacity (OEO) as measures. Higher values of these indicators demonstrate lower information disclosure quality. Table 7, columns (5) - (6), present the regression results, showing that RTLS improves the information disclosure quality of NEEQ high-tech SMEs.
5.7 Heterogeneity analysis
Considering that firms with different ownership structures and levels of marketization may face varying financing costs and information disclosure quality [40–42], this section explores how RTLS affects innovation investment and substantive innovation output of NEEQ high-tech SMEs under different ownership structures and marketization levels.
5.7.1 The impact of property rights nature.
Under the context of market-oriented reforms, state-owned enterprises (SOEs) continue to have access to abundant resources. Significant differences exist between SOEs and non-SOEs in terms of financing constraints and innovation-driven dynamics. Consequently, the impact of RTLS on firms’ innovation input and substantive innovation output varies significantly between the two.
First, scarce resources are predominantly controlled by the government, and local government performance objectives lead to greater support for SOEs [43]. As a result, limited resources are disproportionately allocated to SOEs [40], while non-SOEs face higher levels of credit discrimination [44,45]. Thus, non-SOEs experience more severe financing constraints, and improved stock liquidity under RTLS is more likely to enhance their innovation input. Second, compared to SOEs, non-SOEs are subject to fewer social responsibility pressures, such as addressing employment issues and driving local economic growth. Consequently, the improvement in resource allocation efficiency is more likely to promote substantive innovation outcomes in non-SOEs and conduct subsamples test.
To examine the differential effects of RTLS on innovation input and substantive innovation output between SOEs and non-SOEs, this study categorizes the entire sample based on whether the ultimate controller is state capital. We conduct subsample regressions for Models (1) and (2) separately for SOEs and non-SOEs. Columns (1) - (4) of Table 8 present the effects of RTLS on innovation input and substantive innovation output for SOEs and non-SOEs. The p-value of the inter-group coefficient difference test is significantly positive and the DID coefficient is only significantly positive for non-SOEs, indicating that RTLS promotes innovation input and substantive innovation output in non-SOEs.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
5.7.2 The impact of marketization level.
Differences in regional resource endowments, policy conditions, and geographic locations result in significant variations in the degree of marketization across regions [46]. Consequently, the impact of RTLS on innovation input and substantive innovation output among NEEQ high-tech SMEs may exhibit heterogeneity depending on the level of marketization in different regions.
First, regions with a high degree of marketization possess more abundant innovation resources. These regions often have well-developed innovation ecosystems, including incubators, accelerators, technology partners, and industrial clusters. Such networks and collaborations facilitate knowledge sharing, resource integration, and mutual innovation promotion. Additionally, highly marketized regions tend to attract a concentration of talented professionals and technological resources, creating an agglomeration effect. The abundance of innovation resources in these areas further attracts more innovation-driven firms, resulting in a higher density of such firms in highly marketized regions. Second, regions with a high degree of marketization typically place greater emphasis on intellectual property (IP) protection and maintain a more robust and stringent IP protection environment. A strong IP protection system provides an institutional foundation for enhancing the efficiency of R&D investment and its subsequent output, enabling enterprises to better translate R&D inputs into performance outcomes [47].
Based on the above analysis, we argue that RTLS’s role in promoting innovation input and substantive innovation output is more pronounced in highly marketized regions. Accordingly, referring to Gao et al. (2023) [48], we divide the full sample into high-marketization and low-marketization subsamples based on the Fan Gang Marketization Index and conduct subsample regressions. Columns (5) - (8) of Table 8 present the regression results. Although the p-value of the inter-group coefficient difference test is not significant, the DID coefficient in the high-marketization group is larger and more significant compared to the low-marketization group. This indicates that the implementation of RTLS can enhance innovation input and substantial innovation output for NEEQ high-tech SMEs in high-marketization regions.
5.8 Further analysis
5.8.1 RTLS and innovation efficiency.
R&D activities exhibit strong positive externalities, as firms investing heavily in R&D cannot fully capture the residual benefits generated by such activities [49]. Furthermore, the presence of financing constraints further suppresses the innovation incentives of high-tech SMEs. To address the insufficient innovation drive caused by market failures, the government has introduced a series of industrial support policies, including fiscal subsidies and various tax incentives for qualifying firms. As industrial policies become widespread, existing studies find that these policies essentially represent an incomplete contract. The incompleteness of this contract lies in the fact that neither the government nor firms can fully anticipate future events, and no reliable third party exists to ensure the effective enforcement of the contract [50]. This incompleteness leads to information asymmetry during policy implementation, making it difficult to achieve the intended policy objectives and ultimately reducing innovation efficiency [51]. The fundamental reason behind this phenomenon lies in the inherent disadvantage of the government compared to the market in the aspect of information screening.
RTLS aims to address the innovation challenges of high-tech SMEs by reforming the capital market and leveraging market-oriented mechanisms. For NEEQ high-tech SMEs, RTLS has two major implications. On the one hand, the emphasis on information disclosure standards in RTLS improves the quality of information disclosure, forcing them to reduce opportunistic innovation behaviors and thereby enhancing innovation efficiency. On the other hand, the financing convenience and valuation enhancement brought about by RTLS attract more investors, increase stock liquidity, and lower financing costs for NEEQ high-tech SMEs. This provides alternative channels for obtaining innovation funding, enabling them to spontaneously reduce innovation motivated solely by policy incentives and further improve innovation efficiency. To test the validity of the above analysis, we design the following model:
(4)
Where Effit+1 represents the innovation efficiency of firm i in year t + 1, measured by the ratio of invention patents to R&D expenditure. The definitions of other variables are consistent with those in Model (1). Column (1) of Table 9 shows that the coefficient of DID is significantly positive at the 1% level, indicating that the implementation of RTLS can improve the innovation efficiency of NEEQ high-tech SMEs.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
5.8.2 RTLS and fiscal subsidies.
Before the implementation of RTLS, high-tech SMEs faced significant challenges in accessing affordable financing, which served as a primary obstacle to their innovation activities [52]. Although the NEEQ provided a channel for equity financing, its relative independence and high investor thresholds led to significant liquidity issues within the market as the number of listed firms increased. To support SMEs’ innovation activities and alleviate their ex-ante financing constraints, the government continuously increased fiscal subsidies.
Regarding the effectiveness of fiscal subsidies in stimulating innovation, two mainstream perspectives exist. The first is the “effective subsidy” view, which posits that fiscal subsidies incentivize firms to increase R&D investment, thereby promoting innovation [53,54]. The second is the “ineffective subsidy” view, which argues that fiscal subsidies disrupt market competition mechanisms, increase transaction costs [51], and lead to rent-seeking behaviors [55], thereby fostering innovation mimicry. This mimicry encourages firms to adopt a “quantity-over-quality” strategy in innovation [56]. The above literature indicates that while fiscal subsidies can alleviate SMEs’ ex-ante financing constraints and thereby promote innovation from a financing perspective, they may distort market resource allocation mechanisms from an agency perspective. The increase in free cash flow resulting from fiscal subsidies exacerbates agency problems, encouraging firms to engage in fraudulent practices to obtain subsidies, which ultimately undermines the efficiency of fiscal subsidies in promoting innovation.
However, following the implementation of RTLS, the improved liquidity of stocks among NEEQ high-tech SMEs may enhance financing convenience. Whether this reduces their reliance on fiscal subsidies for innovation remains an open question. To explore this issue, we construct the following model:
(5)
Where Lnsubit is calculated as the natural logarithm of the total fiscal subsidies received by the firm i in the year t plus one. To evaluate whether the implementation of RTLS reduces the reliance of NEEQ high-tech SMEs on fiscal subsidies for innovation, we introduce an interaction term between DID and Lnsub. The focus is on the sign of the interaction term coefficient γ5. If RTLS reduces the reliance of high-tech SMEs on fiscal subsidies for innovation, we expect γ5 to be significantly negative. The definitions of other variables are consistent with those in the main regression model. Columns (2) - (3) of Table 8 present the regression results of Model (5). The results show that the coefficient of DID×Lnsub is significantly negative, indicating that the financing convenience brought by RTLS reduces the reliance of high-tech SMEs on fiscal subsidies for innovation.
6. Conclusions and policy implications
Using specialized and sophisticated SMEs listed on the NEEQ from 2016 to 2022 as our research sample, we empirically examine the impact of RTLS on high-tech SMEs’ innovation activities. We find that RTLS can enhance innovation input by increasing stock liquidity and promote substantial innovation output through improving information disclosure quality among NEEQ high-tech SMEs. The conclusions remain robust after robustness tests including replacing dependent variables, entropy balance test, and excluding other relative polices. Heterogeneity analysis shows that the positive effects of RTLS on high-tech SMEs’ innovation activities are more pronounced in non-SOEs and regions with higher marketization. Lastly, we also find that RTLS can enhance innovation efficiency and lessen dependence on fiscal subsidies to promote innovation of NEEQ high-tech SMEs. Based on the above conclusions, we propose the following recommendations.
Firstly, compared to government intervention measures such as fiscal subsidies, the market holds more advantages in promoting innovation. On the one hand, financing through financial markets can provide firms with a continuous stream of innovation capital, alleviating fiscal pressures on the government. This represents a more cost-effective and sustainable way of stimulating innovation compared to fiscal subsidies. On the other hand, the market incurs lower informational costs, improving resource allocation efficiency, while robust market oversight can reduce opportunistic innovation behavior by firms. This helps break the current reliance of firms on fiscal subsidies to sustain innovation. Therefore, in encouraging innovation, the government should focus on adhering to market principles and leveraging market mechanisms to drive innovation rather than directly intervening in the innovation process.
Secondly, the government should further refine the positioning of the NEEQ within the capital market and strengthen its role as an innovation financing platform for early-stage high-tech SMEs. For such firms, significant upfront R&D investments and financing constraints pose substantial barriers to innovation input and output. As the financing platform for early-stage high-tech SMEs, the key to the NEEQ’s role lies in improving internal liquidity and trading activity within the board to ensure that firms have access to sustained equity financing. Enhancing the liquidity and activity of the NEEQ board requires greater participation from external investors, which, in turn, depends on the quality of listed firms within the board. To this end, efforts should be made to build a multi-tiered capital market system, attracting more high-potential innovative firms to enter the NEEQ market. This would ensure a steady pipeline of promising firms for higher-tier boards and incentivize top-performing firms within the NEEQ to transition to higher-level boards.
Finally, regulatory authorities should continuously strengthen penalties for violations of information disclosure to firmly delineate “red lines” against corporate fraud. Under the comprehensive reform of the registration-based system, the market will have greater discretion. To maintain the stable and efficient functioning of market rules, it is imperative to strictly regulate corporate information disclosure practices. Regulatory agencies should clearly define the quality requirements for information disclosure within the NEEQ board, increase the cost of non-compliance, and establish strong connections between fraudulent disclosure behaviors and the interests of companies and relevant individuals. In addition to enhancing monetary penalties, reputational and credit costs should also be emphasized, imposing multi-faceted penalties for violations. This approach would foster a sound information disclosure environment within the board.
This study has several limitations, which also suggest directions for future research. First, the sample is restricted to NEEQ high-tech SMEs, excluding non-NEEQ high-tech SMEs. This limitation may reduce the generalizability of the findings to a broader population of high-tech SMEs. Future research could explore the impact of the RTLS on a wider range of high-tech SMEs to enhance the external validity of the conclusions. Second, the sample period spans 2016 to 2022, covering the early stage of RTLS. However, this timeframe may be insufficient to capture the long-term effects of the policy, particularly the sustained innovation performance of firms after transferring to the main board market. Future research could further examine the long-term impact of RTLS on the innovation activities of high-tech SMEs, as well as the evolution of their innovation performance post-transfer. Third, corporate R&D investment and patent innovation encompass multiple categories, but this study does not distinguish between different types of innovation activities. Future research could conduct a more granular analysis of the heterogeneous effects of RTLS on various types of innovation. Finally, potential unobserved factors (e.g., firms opting for transfer listing may inherently possess stronger innovation capabilities, or the influence of other concurrent policies) could introduce estimation bias in this study. Future research could employ more robust identification strategies to address endogeneity concerns and further validate the causal impact of RTLS on the innovation activities of high-tech SMEs.
Supporting information
S1. Dataset.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0324208.s001
(DTA)
References
1. 1. Wang Z, Hu X, Yu F. How does CEO narcissism affect enterprise ambidextrous technological innovation? The mediating role of corporate social responsibility. PLoS One. 2023;18(1):e0280758. pmid:36662757
* View Article
* PubMed/NCBI
* Google Scholar
2. 2. Tu G, Chen H, Zhu C. Research on financing countermeasures of online game SMEs based on the identification of intangible assets information. PLoS One. 2024;19(3):e0291338. pmid:38527019
* View Article
* PubMed/NCBI
* Google Scholar
3. 3. Sun H, Yang X, Tang X, Peng F. How innovation funding leads enterprises to engage in research and development: Small and medium enterprises’ perspective. PLoS One. 2023;18(7):e0289166. pmid:37490503
* View Article
* PubMed/NCBI
* Google Scholar
4. 4. Yao L, Yang X. Can digital finance boost SME innovation by easing financing constraints?: Evidence from Chinese GEM-listed companies. PLoS One. 2022;17(3):e0264647. pmid:35239717
* View Article
* PubMed/NCBI
* Google Scholar
5. 5. Hall BH. The Financing of Research and Development. Oxford Review of Economic Policy. 2002;18(1):35–51.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
6. 6. Cassar G. The financing of business start-ups. Journal of Business Venturing. 2004;19(2):261–83.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
7. 7. Stiglitz J. Markets, market failures, and development. Am Econ Rev. 1989;79(2):197–203.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
8. 8. Keech WR, Munger MC. The anatomy of government failure. Public Choice. 2015;164(1–2):1–42.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
9. 9. David PA, Hall BH, Toole AA. Is public R&D a complement or substitute for private R&D? A review of the econometric evidence. Research Policy. 2000;29(4–5):497–529.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
10. 10. Li J, Xu J. The effect of the registration-based IPO reform on price efficiency: evidence from China. Applied Economics Letters. 2022;31(7):608–17.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
11. 11. Deng Q, Dai L, Yang Z, Zhou Z-G, Hussein M, Chen D, et al. The impacts of regulation regime changes on ChiNext IPOs: Effects of 2013 and 2020 reforms on initial return, fair value and overreaction. International Review of Financial Analysis. 2023;89:102794.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
12. 12. Liao X. Registration system and IPO pricing efficiency: Evidence from China. Applied Economics. 2023;56(39):4730–43.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
13. 13. Li J, Li R. IPO policy and IPO underpricing: Evidence from the registration-based IPO reform in China. Finance Research Letters. 2022;47:102623.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
14. 14. Li Q, He L, Gou X, Ren Y. The registration-based IPO reform and the cost of equity capital: evidence from China. Finance Research Letters. 2024;67:105790.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
15. 15. Jiang C, Xu J, Xu Q, Fu W. Can we rest easy under the registration-based IPO reform? Evidence from the Chinese growth enterprise market. Economic Analysis and Policy. 2024;83:990–1006.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
16. 16. Meuleman M, De Maeseneire W. Do R&D subsidies affect SMEs’ access to external financing?. Research Policy. 2012;41(3):580–91.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
17. 17. Yan Y-X, Kim Y-G, Shin H-J. A Study on the Impact of Fiscal and Tax Policy on R&D Innovation in SMEs: Evidence from China. Korea Int Trade Res Inst. 2021;17(2):57–68.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
18. 18. Xu P, Zhang M, Gui M. How R&D Financial Subsidies, Regional R&D Input, and Intellectual Property Protection Affect the Sustainable Patent Output of SMEs: Evidence from China. Sustainability. 2020;12(3):1207.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
19. 19. Li Q, Wang M, Xiangli L. Do government subsidies promote new-energy firms’ innovation? Evidence from dynamic and threshold models. Journal of Cleaner Production. 2021;286:124992.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
20. 20. Li Y, Dong X, Sun J. R&D project subsidy V.S. government innovation reward: The effectiveness on corporate innovation. China Economic Review. 2024;88:102288.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
21. 21. Li Q, Wang J, Cao G, Zhang J. Financial constraints, government subsidies, and corporate innovation. PLoS One. 2021;16(11):e0259642. pmid:34758030
* View Article
* PubMed/NCBI
* Google Scholar
22. 22. Ye S, Yi S, Fangjing S, Yuzhu Q. Government intervention, internal control, and technology innovation of SMEs in China. Front Psychol. 2022;13:960025. pmid:35978797
* View Article
* PubMed/NCBI
* Google Scholar
23. 23. BROWN JR, FAZZARI SM, PETERSEN BC. Financing Innovation and Growth: Cash Flow, External Equity, and the 1990s R&D Boom. The Journal of Finance. 2009;64(1):151–85.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
24. 24. Beck T, Levine R. Industry growth and capital allocation:. Journal of Financial Economics. 2002;64(2):147–80.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
25. 25. Klapper LF, Love I. Corporate governance, investor protection, and performance in emerging markets. Journal of Corporate Finance. 2004;10(5):703–28.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
26. 26. Porta RL, Lopez-de-Silanes F, Shleifer A. The Economic Consequences of Legal Origins. Journal of Economic Literature. 2008;46(2):285–332.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
27. 27. Bekaert G, Harvey CR. Foreign Speculators and Emerging Equity Markets. The Journal of Finance. 2000;55(2):565–613.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
28. 28. Greenwood J, Jovanovic B. Financial Development, Growth, and the Distribution of Income. Journal of Political Economy. 1990;98(5, Part 1):1076–107.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
29. 29. Teece DJ. Explicating dynamic capabilities: the nature and microfoundations of (sustainable) enterprise performance. Strategic Management Journal. 2007;28(13):1319–50.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
30. 30. Barry CB, Brown SJ. Limited information as a source of risk. JPM. 1986;12(2):66–72.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
31. 31. Pound J. Proxy contests and the efficiency of shareholder oversight. Journal of Financial Economics. 1988;20:237–65.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
32. 32. Healy PM, Palepu KG. Information asymmetry, corporate disclosure, and the capital markets: A review of the empirical disclosure literature. Journal of Accounting and Economics. 2001;31(1–3):405–40.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
33. 33. Jacobson LS, Lalonde RJ, Sullivan DG. Earnings losses of displaced workers. American Economic Review. 1993; 83(4): 685–709. http://doi.org/10.2307/2117574
* View Article
* Google Scholar
34. 34. Liu Q, Lu Y. Firm investment and exporting: Evidence from China’s value-added tax reform. Journal of International Economics. 2015;97(2):392–403.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
35. 35. Cai X, Lu Y, Wu M, Yu L. Does environmental regulation drive away inbound foreign direct investment? Evidence from a quasi-natural experiment in China. Journal of Development Economics. 2016;123:73–85.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
36. 36. Lu Y, Gao Y, Zhang Y, Wang J. Can the green finance policy force the green transformation of high-polluting enterprises? A quasi-natural experiment based on “Green Credit Guidelines”. Energy Economics. 2022;114:106265.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
37. 37. Hainmueller J. Entropy Balancing for Causal Effects: A Multivariate Reweighting Method to Produce Balanced Samples in Observational Studies. Polit anal. 2012;20(1):25–46.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
38. 38. Amihud Y, Mendelson H. Asset pricing and the bid-ask spread. Journal of Financial Economics. 1986;17(2):223–49.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
39. 39. Fang VW, Tian X, Tice S. Does Stock Liquidity Enhance or Impede Firm Innovation?. The Journal of Finance. 2014;69(5):2085–125.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
40. 40. Allen F, Qian J, Qian M. Law, finance, and economic growth in China. Journal of Financial Economics. 2005;77(1):57–116.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
41. 41. Chen G, Firth M, Gao DN, Rui OM. Ownership structure, corporate governance, and fraud: Evidence from China. Journal of Corporate Finance. 2006;12(3):424–48.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
42. 42. Faccio M, Masulis RW, Mcconnell JJ. Political Connections and Corporate Bailouts. The Journal of Finance. 2006;61(6):2597–635.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
43. 43. Shleifer A, Vishny RW. Politicians and Firms. The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1994;109(4):995–1025.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
44. 44. Fan J, Wong T, Zhang T. Politically connected CEOs, corporate governance, and Post-IPO performance of China’s newly partially privatized firms⋆. Journal of Financial Economics. 2007;84(2):330–57.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
45. 45. Ayyagari M, Demirgüç-Kunt A, Maksimovic V. Formal versus Informal Finance: Evidence from China. Rev Financ Stud. 2010;23(8):3048–97.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
46. 46. Gang Z. Government Intervention vs Marketization in China’s Rural Industries. China Information. 1993;8(1–2):45–73.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
47. 47. Ginarte JC, Park WG. Determinants of patent rights: A cross-national study. Research Policy. 1997;26(3):283–301.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
48. 48. Gao F, Tao Y, Chen D, Cao Y. Stringent financial regulation and corporate R&D investment: Evidence from a quasi-natural experiment in China. Finance Research Letters. 2023;55:103933.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
49. 49. Romer PM. Endogenous Technological Change. Journal of Political Economy. 1990;98(5, Part 2):S71–102.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
50. 50. Grossman SJ, Hart OD. The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration. Journal of Political Economy. 1986;94(4):691–719.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
51. 51. Tirole J. Incomplete Contracts: Where do We Stand?. Econometrica. 1999;67(4):741–81.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
52. 52. Gu F, Gao J, Zhu X, Ye J. The impact of digital inclusive finance on SMEs’ technological innovation activities-Empirical analysis based on the data of new third board enterprises. PLoS One. 2023;18(11):e0293500. pmid:37917741
* View Article
* PubMed/NCBI
* Google Scholar
53. 53. Lee EY, Cin BC. The effect of risk-sharing government subsidy on corporate R&D investment: Empirical evidence from Korea. Technological Forecasting and Social Change. 2010;77(6):881–90.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
54. 54. Bronzini R, Iachini E. Are Incentives for R&D Effective? Evidence from a Regression Discontinuity Approach. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy. 2014;6(4):100–34.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
55. 55. Murphy KM, Shleifer A, Vishny RW. The Allocation of Talent: Implications for Growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1991;106(2):503.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
56. 56. Teece DJ. Business Models, Business Strategy and Innovation. Long Range Planning. 2010;43(2–3):172–94.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
Citation: Du J, Lu D (2025) Registration-based transfer listing system and high-tech SME innovation: Research on China’s specialized and sophisticated SMEs listed on the National Equities Exchange and Quotations. PLoS One 20(5): e0324208. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0324208
About the Authors:
Junjie Du
Contributed equally to this work with: Junjie Du, Dong Lu
Roles: Data curation, Investigation, Methodology, Resources, Software, Validation, Visualization, Writing – original draft
E-mail: [email protected]
Affiliation: School of Accounting, Southwestern University of Finance and Economics, Chengdu, Sichuan, China
ORICD: https://orcid.org/0009-0003-9972-9968
Dong Lu
Contributed equally to this work with: Junjie Du, Dong Lu
Roles: Conceptualization, Formal analysis, Funding acquisition, Project administration, Supervision, Writing – review & editing
Affiliation: School of Accounting, Southwestern University of Finance and Economics, Chengdu, Sichuan, China
1. Wang Z, Hu X, Yu F. How does CEO narcissism affect enterprise ambidextrous technological innovation? The mediating role of corporate social responsibility. PLoS One. 2023;18(1):e0280758. pmid:36662757
2. Tu G, Chen H, Zhu C. Research on financing countermeasures of online game SMEs based on the identification of intangible assets information. PLoS One. 2024;19(3):e0291338. pmid:38527019
3. Sun H, Yang X, Tang X, Peng F. How innovation funding leads enterprises to engage in research and development: Small and medium enterprises’ perspective. PLoS One. 2023;18(7):e0289166. pmid:37490503
4. Yao L, Yang X. Can digital finance boost SME innovation by easing financing constraints?: Evidence from Chinese GEM-listed companies. PLoS One. 2022;17(3):e0264647. pmid:35239717
5. Hall BH. The Financing of Research and Development. Oxford Review of Economic Policy. 2002;18(1):35–51.
6. Cassar G. The financing of business start-ups. Journal of Business Venturing. 2004;19(2):261–83.
7. Stiglitz J. Markets, market failures, and development. Am Econ Rev. 1989;79(2):197–203.
8. Keech WR, Munger MC. The anatomy of government failure. Public Choice. 2015;164(1–2):1–42.
9. David PA, Hall BH, Toole AA. Is public R&D a complement or substitute for private R&D? A review of the econometric evidence. Research Policy. 2000;29(4–5):497–529.
10. Li J, Xu J. The effect of the registration-based IPO reform on price efficiency: evidence from China. Applied Economics Letters. 2022;31(7):608–17.
11. Deng Q, Dai L, Yang Z, Zhou Z-G, Hussein M, Chen D, et al. The impacts of regulation regime changes on ChiNext IPOs: Effects of 2013 and 2020 reforms on initial return, fair value and overreaction. International Review of Financial Analysis. 2023;89:102794.
12. Liao X. Registration system and IPO pricing efficiency: Evidence from China. Applied Economics. 2023;56(39):4730–43.
13. Li J, Li R. IPO policy and IPO underpricing: Evidence from the registration-based IPO reform in China. Finance Research Letters. 2022;47:102623.
14. Li Q, He L, Gou X, Ren Y. The registration-based IPO reform and the cost of equity capital: evidence from China. Finance Research Letters. 2024;67:105790.
15. Jiang C, Xu J, Xu Q, Fu W. Can we rest easy under the registration-based IPO reform? Evidence from the Chinese growth enterprise market. Economic Analysis and Policy. 2024;83:990–1006.
16. Meuleman M, De Maeseneire W. Do R&D subsidies affect SMEs’ access to external financing?. Research Policy. 2012;41(3):580–91.
17. Yan Y-X, Kim Y-G, Shin H-J. A Study on the Impact of Fiscal and Tax Policy on R&D Innovation in SMEs: Evidence from China. Korea Int Trade Res Inst. 2021;17(2):57–68.
18. Xu P, Zhang M, Gui M. How R&D Financial Subsidies, Regional R&D Input, and Intellectual Property Protection Affect the Sustainable Patent Output of SMEs: Evidence from China. Sustainability. 2020;12(3):1207.
19. Li Q, Wang M, Xiangli L. Do government subsidies promote new-energy firms’ innovation? Evidence from dynamic and threshold models. Journal of Cleaner Production. 2021;286:124992.
20. Li Y, Dong X, Sun J. R&D project subsidy V.S. government innovation reward: The effectiveness on corporate innovation. China Economic Review. 2024;88:102288.
21. Li Q, Wang J, Cao G, Zhang J. Financial constraints, government subsidies, and corporate innovation. PLoS One. 2021;16(11):e0259642. pmid:34758030
22. Ye S, Yi S, Fangjing S, Yuzhu Q. Government intervention, internal control, and technology innovation of SMEs in China. Front Psychol. 2022;13:960025. pmid:35978797
23. BROWN JR, FAZZARI SM, PETERSEN BC. Financing Innovation and Growth: Cash Flow, External Equity, and the 1990s R&D Boom. The Journal of Finance. 2009;64(1):151–85.
24. Beck T, Levine R. Industry growth and capital allocation:. Journal of Financial Economics. 2002;64(2):147–80.
25. Klapper LF, Love I. Corporate governance, investor protection, and performance in emerging markets. Journal of Corporate Finance. 2004;10(5):703–28.
26. Porta RL, Lopez-de-Silanes F, Shleifer A. The Economic Consequences of Legal Origins. Journal of Economic Literature. 2008;46(2):285–332.
27. Bekaert G, Harvey CR. Foreign Speculators and Emerging Equity Markets. The Journal of Finance. 2000;55(2):565–613.
28. Greenwood J, Jovanovic B. Financial Development, Growth, and the Distribution of Income. Journal of Political Economy. 1990;98(5, Part 1):1076–107.
29. Teece DJ. Explicating dynamic capabilities: the nature and microfoundations of (sustainable) enterprise performance. Strategic Management Journal. 2007;28(13):1319–50.
30. Barry CB, Brown SJ. Limited information as a source of risk. JPM. 1986;12(2):66–72.
31. Pound J. Proxy contests and the efficiency of shareholder oversight. Journal of Financial Economics. 1988;20:237–65.
32. Healy PM, Palepu KG. Information asymmetry, corporate disclosure, and the capital markets: A review of the empirical disclosure literature. Journal of Accounting and Economics. 2001;31(1–3):405–40.
33. Jacobson LS, Lalonde RJ, Sullivan DG. Earnings losses of displaced workers. American Economic Review. 1993; 83(4): 685–709. http://doi.org/10.2307/2117574
34. Liu Q, Lu Y. Firm investment and exporting: Evidence from China’s value-added tax reform. Journal of International Economics. 2015;97(2):392–403.
35. Cai X, Lu Y, Wu M, Yu L. Does environmental regulation drive away inbound foreign direct investment? Evidence from a quasi-natural experiment in China. Journal of Development Economics. 2016;123:73–85.
36. Lu Y, Gao Y, Zhang Y, Wang J. Can the green finance policy force the green transformation of high-polluting enterprises? A quasi-natural experiment based on “Green Credit Guidelines”. Energy Economics. 2022;114:106265.
37. Hainmueller J. Entropy Balancing for Causal Effects: A Multivariate Reweighting Method to Produce Balanced Samples in Observational Studies. Polit anal. 2012;20(1):25–46.
38. Amihud Y, Mendelson H. Asset pricing and the bid-ask spread. Journal of Financial Economics. 1986;17(2):223–49.
39. Fang VW, Tian X, Tice S. Does Stock Liquidity Enhance or Impede Firm Innovation?. The Journal of Finance. 2014;69(5):2085–125.
40. Allen F, Qian J, Qian M. Law, finance, and economic growth in China. Journal of Financial Economics. 2005;77(1):57–116.
41. Chen G, Firth M, Gao DN, Rui OM. Ownership structure, corporate governance, and fraud: Evidence from China. Journal of Corporate Finance. 2006;12(3):424–48.
42. Faccio M, Masulis RW, Mcconnell JJ. Political Connections and Corporate Bailouts. The Journal of Finance. 2006;61(6):2597–635.
43. Shleifer A, Vishny RW. Politicians and Firms. The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1994;109(4):995–1025.
44. Fan J, Wong T, Zhang T. Politically connected CEOs, corporate governance, and Post-IPO performance of China’s newly partially privatized firms⋆. Journal of Financial Economics. 2007;84(2):330–57.
45. Ayyagari M, Demirgüç-Kunt A, Maksimovic V. Formal versus Informal Finance: Evidence from China. Rev Financ Stud. 2010;23(8):3048–97.
46. Gang Z. Government Intervention vs Marketization in China’s Rural Industries. China Information. 1993;8(1–2):45–73.
47. Ginarte JC, Park WG. Determinants of patent rights: A cross-national study. Research Policy. 1997;26(3):283–301.
48. Gao F, Tao Y, Chen D, Cao Y. Stringent financial regulation and corporate R&D investment: Evidence from a quasi-natural experiment in China. Finance Research Letters. 2023;55:103933.
49. Romer PM. Endogenous Technological Change. Journal of Political Economy. 1990;98(5, Part 2):S71–102.
50. Grossman SJ, Hart OD. The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration. Journal of Political Economy. 1986;94(4):691–719.
51. Tirole J. Incomplete Contracts: Where do We Stand?. Econometrica. 1999;67(4):741–81.
52. Gu F, Gao J, Zhu X, Ye J. The impact of digital inclusive finance on SMEs’ technological innovation activities-Empirical analysis based on the data of new third board enterprises. PLoS One. 2023;18(11):e0293500. pmid:37917741
53. Lee EY, Cin BC. The effect of risk-sharing government subsidy on corporate R&D investment: Empirical evidence from Korea. Technological Forecasting and Social Change. 2010;77(6):881–90.
54. Bronzini R, Iachini E. Are Incentives for R&D Effective? Evidence from a Regression Discontinuity Approach. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy. 2014;6(4):100–34.
55. Murphy KM, Shleifer A, Vishny RW. The Allocation of Talent: Implications for Growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1991;106(2):503.
56. Teece DJ. Business Models, Business Strategy and Innovation. Long Range Planning. 2010;43(2–3):172–94.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer
© 2025 Du, Lu. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License: http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ (the “License”), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited. Notwithstanding the ProQuest Terms and Conditions, you may use this content in accordance with the terms of the License.
Abstract
In China, high-tech small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) are a crucial component of the innovation ecosystem, and how to effectively promote innovation within these firms has become a pressing challenge for the government. Against the backdrop of the registration-based reform, we use a sample of specialized and sophisticated SMEs listed on the National Equities Exchange and Quotations (NEEQ) from 2016 to 2022 to empirically examine the impact of the registration-based transfer listing system (RTLS) on the innovation activities of NEEQ high-tech SMEs. We find that RTLS can enhance innovation input by improving stock liquidity. Meanwhile, we find that RTLS can also promote substantive innovation output by strengthening information disclosure. We further document that the positive effect is more pronounced in highly marketized regions and among non-state-owned enterprises. Further analysis shows that RTLS can enhance innovation efficiency and lessen reliance on fiscal subsidies to promote innovation for NEEQ high-tech SMEs.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer