ABSTRACT
This article explores how the social enterprise concept is used in Québec. Focusing on the historical, institutional, and current conceptual understanding of the social economy in Québec, it explores the related definitions, terminology, and typologies currently in use. The term "social enterprise" is near absent in Québec, mainly due to the highly recognized notion of social economy. However, not all Québec enterprises that pursue social goals fit into the social economy institutional definition. This article proposes a conceptual framework for understanding the modalities of Québec's field of social economy and other social purpose enterprises. It suggests that "social enterprises" in Québec are those that participate in the social purposes of the social economy without sharing the core and institutionalized characteristics of social economy enterprises.
RÉSUMÉ
Cet article explore l'usage du terme « entreprise sociale » au Québec. Se basant sur des aspects historiques, institutionnels et conceptuels, l'article explore les définitions et les typologies qui ont cours aujourd'hui. L'expression « entreprise sociale » est rarement mentionnée, dû à la forte reconnaissance de l'économie sociale. Toutefois, il existe des entreprises au Québec qui, tout en poursuivant des objectifs sociaux, ne correspondent pas à la définition institutionnelle de l'économie sociale. La principale contribution de cet article est de proposer un cadre conceptuel pour comprendre le champ de l'économie sociale et des autres entreprises à finalité sociale. Il suggère que les « entreprises sociales » sont celles qui participent aux objectifs sociaux de l'économie sociale mais qui n'en ont pas les caractéristiques institutionnelles.
KEYWORDS / MOTS CLÉS : Social enterprise; Social economy; Conceptual framework; Québec / Entreprise sociale; Économie sociale; Cadre conceptuel, Québec
INTRODUCTION
As part of the International Comparative Social Enterprise Models (ICSEM) research project led by researchers of the EMES International Research Network, this article explores how the social enterprise concept is used at present in Québec. The widespread concept in Québec is that of the social economy. Its definition, today institutionalized in a specific legislation, refers to the production of goods and services by nonprofit associations, mutual societies, and cooperatives, and by a set of guiding principles these organizations should follow. Focusing on the historical, institutional, and current conceptual understanding of the social economy in Québec, the article explores the related definitions, terminology, and typologies in usage at the present time.
The term "social enterprise" is near absent in Québec, mainly due to the highly recognized notion of social economy. However, not all of Québec enterprises related to the social economy fit into the social economy institutional definition. Should these be named "social enterprises?" We explore this question by comparing the notion of social enterprise, as defined by EMES, to the Québec notion of social economy, and by examining more closely the characteristics of enterprises that pursue social goals in Québec.
Following the ICSEM project's guidelines, this article is comprised of three sections. The first section presents the main historical, contextual, and conceptual features of social economy and social enterprises in Québec. The second section proposes a framework for classifying Québec's social economy and related enterprises in three main categories. Finally, the third section describes these three categories, presenting some exemplary cases that illustrate the main characteristics of each.
HISTORICAL, CONTEXTUAL, AND CONCEPTUAL ANALYSIS OF SOCIAL ECONOMY AND SOCIAL ENTERPRISES IN QUÉBEC
Historical analysis of social economy in Québec
In Québec, the widespread concept referring to so-called social enterprise is the social economy concept. Québec's social economy has a long history that began in the nineteenth century and developed into five major periods and configurations (Lévesque, 2013). The first configuration corresponds to an urban solidarity economy, which manifested in the nineteenth century with the emergence of autonomous, self-managed, and non-market socioeconomic initiatives in response to the harsh conditions of life and work imposed by the progressive development of industrial and commercial capitalism (Lévesque, 2013). Without significant support from social authorities, such as the church, the state, and traditional elites, these initiatives have reconfigured as mutual societies.
The second configuration dates from the early twentieth century and corresponds to a rural, market-oriented social economy that was sponsored by social elites, the church, and public authorities. This period is characterized by the rise of large mutual societies, agricultural cooperatives, as well as savings and credit cooperatives. The third configuration, ushered in by the economic crisis of 1930, represents the "golden age" of cooperatives and saw the emergence of cooperatives in new areas such as fishing, electricity consumption, and housing. Roughly during this time, namely between 1926 and 1956, the number of nonprofit associations also increased fivefold.
However, the momentum and power of these new cooperative sectors began to wane in the 1950s, slowly giving way to the fourth configuration of the 1960s, 1970s, and 1980s. This phase was initially characterized by the expansion of more mature cooperatives during the years of the Quiet Revolution (1960-1970), which were marked by strong economic nationalism. Later, following the economic crisis of the early 1980s, it was characterized by the redirection of state support away from cooperatives and toward private companies, which were considered more likely to survive the impending restructuring of the economy. Still, some cooperative initiatives that had manifested a certain independence from their original state support continued to run their operations.
The fifth configuration took shape in the 1990s with the convergence between the social and solidarity economy in the context of a partnership with the state regarding economic as well as social development. Cooperatives, mutual societies, and associations developed initiatives as responses to the economic crisis and the crisis of the welfare state, providing solutions to the very concrete problems of long-term unemployment, social exclusion, new social needs, and social emergencies (Lévesque, 2013).
Following this long process, the social economy concept finally gained institutional recognition in Québec in the mid-1990s (Lévesque, 2013), namely as a result of the 1996 Summit on Economy and Employment. The definition of the social economy that is widely accepted to this day was originally produced by social economy actors (cooperatives, community-based nonprofit associations, community economic development organizations, etc.) within the Social Economy Working Group created by the Québec government, and that led to the constitution-and institutionalization-of the Chantier de l'économie sociale (in French, "chantier" means construction site, building or work under construction). In this definition, the social economy comprises the activities and organizations associated with collective enterprises that aim to serve their members or community, operate independently of government, incorporate democratic decision-making procedures into their by-laws and work processes, uphold the primacy of people and work over capital in the distribution of profits and revenues, and base their operations on the principle of participatory management, empowerment, and individual and collective responsibility. Social economy finance institutions such as the Réseau d'investissement social du Québec (Québec Social Investment Network) and the Caisse d'économie solidaire Desjardins (a particular Desjardins credit union dedicated namely to the social economy), also contributed to putting this definition into practice throughout Québec. More recently in October 2013, the Québec government officially recognized the social economy concept with the adoption of Bill 27, the Social Economy Act. This law is largely based on the social economy definition of 1996, yet provides a more comprehensive framework by legally institutionalizing the social economy field in the province. As stressed in the law, concretely, this framework law ensures recognition of social economy enterprises (cooperatives, mutual societies, and nonprofit organizations of a commercial nature) by all government departments and bodies.
Contextual analysis of social economy in Québec
Québec's social economy is rich and diversified. We focus here on the main contextual elements that directly impact the definition and boundaries of the social economy field. These elements can be understood on the basis of three different types of definitions and typologies: institutional, applied institutional, and analytical.
Institutional definition and typologies
The first level is the institutional definition brought by the Québec government's recognition of the social economy, followed by a legislation that offers a framework for the social economy based on legal status and overall principles. The Social Economy Act defines the social economy enterprise as "an enterprise whose activities consist, inter alia, in the commercialization or exchange of goods or services, and which is operated, in accordance with the principles set out in the first paragraph, by a cooperative, a mutual society or an association endowed with legal personality" (Québec, 2013, Chapter I, Article 3, our translation). It also institutes the principles that are to guide these activities, featuring their social purpose, democratic governance, economic viability, and non-distribution or limited distribution of surplus as well as remaining assets in the event of dissolution. Cooperatives, credit unions, mutual societies, and nonprofit organizations are also each ruled by specific Québec legislations. The Cooperatives' Act defines the eight cooperative principles (concordant with the International Cooperative Alliance) and mentions special provisions for certain types of cooperatives: producers, farmers, consumers, housing, students, workers, workers shareholder, and solidarity cooperatives.
The institutional definition of the social economy in Québec does not include private foundations, hospitals, colleges, university, or churches. It also does not include nonprofit organizations that do not follow the guiding principles of the social economy1 and do not commercialize some of their products or services to clients (including when the client is a government agency or ministry). Thus, the term social economy in Québec covers what in France is called the "social and solidarity-based economy," with the exception of foundations, which are now considered to belong to the social economy in France but not (yet) in Québec (we will develop this matter further on in this article).
Applied-institutional typologies
The second level of typologies is composed of further applied-institutional typologies that are established first by social actors and taken on by public policies and through policy frameworks (such as government programs) that require some form of accreditation (formal public recognition), and are usually based on the nature of the organizations' activities and modes of production. In Québec, this may include work integration enterprises, domestic help social economy enterprises, and daycare centres, which can be incorporated as either nonprofit associations or cooperatives. The term "community economic development" refers to groups that foster local development in both economic and social dimensions-a reality that is also part of the social economy. Another institutional-applied typology is found in Québec's notions of "community action" and "autonomous community action" (ACA), which likewise overlap with the notion of the social economy, although the ACA movement clearly wishes to distinguish itself from the social economy concept in that many of its activities are in no way commercial. Such terminology was established by social actors but has been adopted and institutionalized by public policies, as described earlier.
The government uses the more general terms of "collective entrepreneurship" and "collective enterprises"-as in the Programme d'infrastructure en entrepreneuriat collectif (PIEC)-and the academic world uses them too. Québec practitioners largely accept these terms. For example, the Université du Québec à Montréal (UQAM) post-grad management programs uses the term "social and collective enterprises." This term was chosen based on brainstorming sessions with practitioners coming from various horizons (charitable, non-governmental, community-based, or cooperative organizations), who clearly rejected the term "social enterprise" on the basis that it could introduce confusion about the collective nature of the social economy. McGill University, which recently received a donation to develop this field, likewise opted for the term "social economy" rather than "social enterprise," arguing that "'social economy' is how it is called, here in Québec."2
Analytical typologies
The third level comprises further analytical typologies. Proposed by various researchers, they are based on different attributes or characteristics of the organizations. Benoît Lévesque (2003) proposed a typology based on the nature of the needs (urgent needs or aspirations) and the dominant form of activity (market or non-market), resulting in four groups of social economy organizations. In another of his publications, Lévesque (2002) proposes a typology of forms of entrepreneurship differentiating between three types: capitalist, social, and collective. The main difference between the last two types is the nature of their activities, one being community based and the other collective based. Lévesque (2013) also proposed a typology that categorizes social economy enterprises into three groups according to their objectives, their methods of distribution of surplus, and their governance and representation body. Essentially, this corresponds to cooperatives and mutual societies; nonprofit cooperatives and associations; and unions' funds. According to Lévesque, some charitable foundations could be considered a fourth category; yet, as mentioned above, in Québec charitable foundations are not currently considered part of the social economy. This could change in the near future, as public community-based charitable foundations are increasingly adopting social economy modes of functioning (Fontan, Lévesque, & Charbonneau, 2011; Gazzoli, Jetté, Chamberland, Dumais, & Vaillancourt, 2014).
Focusing on the diversity of organizational forms found in a statistical study of Montréal social economy organizations, Damien Rousselière & Marie J. Bouchard (2011) notice the existence of four transversal models. Each of these models combine, in recurring patterns, different variables that characterize social economy enterprises. These variables concern the hybridization of resources (public/private, market/non-market); the structure of labour (paid/volunteer workers); and the link, or lack thereof, of the social mission to the main economic activity (e.g., housing is both the social mission and the economic activity of cooperative housing organizations, whereas training is the social mission and, for example, woodwork is the economic activity of a work-insertion enterprise). In the data they analyzed, the financing of activities and the type of work were strongly correlated to a particular organizational model. Notwithstanding their legal status (cooperative or nonprofit association), organizations in their study had a high probability of belonging to one of the following patterns of organizational features, or organizational models (Hannan & Freeman, 1989): "volunteer" (10 volunteers or more, low number of wage employees, 50 percent or more of public financing), "professional" (10 or more full-time employees, 10 or more volunteers, 10 or more other employees of other status, 50 percent or more of public financing), "market" (50 percent or more of market revenues, 10 or more full-time employees and 10 or more other employees, low number or absence of volunteers), or "hybrid and emerging" (newly created, low number of wage employees, mixed sources of revenues).
Another typology, proposed by Bouchard, Paulo Cruz Filho, and Martin St-Denis (2011) is based on a substantive definition of the economy (Polanyi, 1944) that allows for the distinction of different types of resources mobilized by social economy organizations (monetary or non-monetary) as well as different mechanisms for allocating these resources. The latter could be market exchange, redistribution, and reciprocity (Laville, 2007; Polanyi, 1944), which are respectively regulated by market price, regulation (law/coercion), and obligation (Enjolras, 2000). Based on this framework, the model classifies social economy enterprises by their dominant source of revenues (public or private) and resource allocation mechanism: a) public/market (e.g., childcare services); b) private/market (e.g., student cooperatives); c) public/non-market (e.g., women's shelters); d) private/non-market (e.g., Amnesty International); e) public/non-monetary (e.g., community recreation centres); or f) private/non-monetary (e.g., local exchange trading systems).
Yvan Comeau, Jacques L. Boucher, Marie-Claire Malo, and Yves Vaillancourt (2001) propose a typology based on the Centre de recherche sur les innovations sociales/Research Centre on Social Innovations (CRISES) case study framework (Comeau, 1996). This typology crosses the institutional dimensions (power structure, internal and external statutory rules) and the organizational dimensions (production, resources, and consumption) that constitute the CRISES conceptual framework to arrive at six types of social and solidarity economy enterprises.
As there is no typology concerning the notion of "social enterprise" in Québec's literature, a more detailed discussion about the "social enterprise" concept in Québec is presented in the next section of this article.
CONCEPTUAL ANALYSIS OF SOCIAL ECONOMY AND SOCIAL ENTERPRISES IN QUÉBEC
The use of the social enterprise concept in Québec
In Québec, the most commonly used term in this field is that of "social economy enterprises" (SEE), sometimes also called "collective enterprises." It constitutes a unifying and inclusive concept (Lévesque, 2013, p. 35) and is used at institutional, analytical, as well as practitioner levels. Thus, although researchers and social actors might use different terminologies, there is only one recognized institutional definition (Lévesque, 2011). As mentioned above, consensus for the latter began forming in 1996 with the inception of the Québec Social Economy Working Group and has been consolidated since 2013 with the adoption of the Social Economy Act (Québec, 2013).
In Canada, the use of the concepts "social enterprise" and "social entrepreneurship" is relatively recent (Fontan, 2011, p. 43) and varies by province (Mendell, 2010, p. 243). According to Marguerite Mendell (2010, p. 251), despite Canada's geographical proximity to the United States, "the culture of individualism that underlies social entrepreneurship" in the US model is less present, and this constitutes an important and distinct feature of the social economy in Canada. In Québec, however, the term "social enterprise" is hardly ever used (Mendell, 2010, p. 243)-at least by the French-speaking population. This is because the social economy tradition is rooted in the associative and mutual movements of the nineteenth century (Lévesque, 2013), in addition to having affinities with the Latin and French European social and solidarity economy concepts.
However, some organizations that appear to be participating in the social economy do not fit the institutional definition of social economy enterprises. These are mainly organizations that are not incorporated as a cooperative, association (nonprofit organization), or mutual society but are closely linked to the development of the social economy, (e.g., have development funds for social economy and sustainable development, but are governed with a share-owners structure). Some organizations might have practices that are similar to those of social economy organizations, but do not share all of the institutionalized characteristics (e.g., local exchange trade systems that have no monetary-based commercial activities). Thus, although such organizations are sometimes categorized as social enterprises (Mendell, 2010), they are essentially "hybrids" (Spear, 2011) or "uncertain components" (Desroche, 1983) of the social economy as defined in Québec. We will go into more details about those further on in the article.
We also observe in Québec the penetration of related concepts. Enterprises that embrace "corporate social responsibility" and "sustainable development" objectives are becoming more overt about their distinctiveness. The B Corps certification is an example that takes the form of a label attributed to classic private for-profit corporations.3 The B Corps label certifies enterprises that meet standards of social and environmental performance and accountability and transparency, and vouches for corporate social responsibility. These recent developments have brought the "social entrepreneurship" and "social enterprise" terms into Québec's discussion about the social economy concept and related definitions. By and large, the terms are starting to emerge within the English-speaking population of Québec, namely in business schools and in large private foundations (e.g., the McConnell Foundation). However, some actors have also proactively worked for the introduction of these terms into the context of the province, especially in reference to new social and environmental mission-oriented ventures and in organizations based on either collective or individual forms of ownership.
The Institut du Nouveau Monde (INM) and Ashoka Canada are the two main civil organizations working on the promotion of these concepts in Québec. INM is a not-for-profit and non-partisan organization with a mission to encourage civic participation and the renewal of ideas in Québec. In regards to social entrepreneurship, INM has been developing different tools, like scholarships, training programs, and events catering to social entrepreneurs. Moreover, through its program À go, on change le monde!, INM also provides opportunities for young entrepreneurs. The vision of this program highlights the term "social enterprise," in French, as a means to "change the world": "Offrir la possibilité aux jeunes qui veulent changer le monde, de créer une entreprise sociale pour le réaliser" (Institut du Nouveau Monde, 2015). Largely inspired by Ashoka, INM has developed a definition that is "adapted to Québec's reality" of what constitutes a social entrepreneur. According to INM, social entrepreneurs are people who:
identify issues or social needs; put forward a practical and innovative solution in order to promote change and social innovation; use entrepreneurial principles to create and manage an organization; demonstrate unquestionable ethics; work together and involve the community in the project; share experiences in order to promote the transfer of knowledge; demonstrate exemplary leadership; and implement a project with sustainable social benefits. (Institut du Nouveau Monde, 2015, our translation)
INM concludes that social entrepreneurship is part of the social and solidarity economy movement, the part of it that places projects, citizens, communities, and society at the very heart of the enterprise. For its part, Ashoka is an international network of social entrepreneurs that "strives to shape a global, entrepreneurial, competitive citizen sector: one that allows social entrepreneurs to thrive and enables the world's citizens to think and act as change makers" (Ashoka Canada, 2015). Over the years, Ashoka has trained more than 2,700 fellows, 36 of whom are Canadian. Of those, 15 are from Québec, which represents nearly half of the Canadian nominations.
Attentive to these conceptual developments, some of the main organizations linked to Québec's social economy, such as the Chantier de l'économie sociale and the liaison and transfer centre Territoires innovants en économie sociale et solidaire/Innovative Territories in Social and Solidarity Economy (TIESS), have recently expressed their interest in exploring, understanding, and clarifying the definitions as well as the particularities and issues concerning ideas related to "social entrepreneurship" and "social enterprise." One of the first actions was the creation of a working group by TIESS in mid-December 2014. The purpose of this working group is to review the definitions and issues surrounding the concepts of "social entrepreneurship" and "social enterprise," and to understand how they are related to the social economy concept in Québec.
Are Québec social economy enterprises, social enterprises in the EMES definition?
The relative absence in Québec of the term "social enterprise" in current institutional, academic, and practitioner usage and debates does not mean, however, that the concept is totally incompatible with that of "social economy enterprises." They overlap and are related, especially when we refer to the definition of social enterprises as proposed by the EMES Research Network. When comparing the legal definition of the social economy in Québec with the EMES social enterprise definition (see Table 1), it becomes clear that Québec's social economy enterprises fit most of the EMES social enterprise criteria with some exceptions, the two most notable being:
1. The Québec Social Economy Act includes all cooperatives, mutual societies, and associations running economic activities, whereas the EMES definition is open to other non-social economy legal statuses (namely private for-profit share-owners' companies) but excludes cooperatives and nonprofit organizations aimed exclusively at the mutual interest of their members. It retains only those that serve the general interest and have a multi-stakeholder membership (Defourny & Nyssens, 2006).
2. The Québec Social Economy Act includes organizations offering little or no paid work, such as housing nonprofit cooperatives and associations, which in Québec own large assets (Bouchard & Hudon, 2008) and would be excluded in the EMES definition. However, the Québec Act does mention that social economy enterprises should aspire to economic viability.
One factor that might explain the near absence of the need for a concept of social enterprise is that in Québec, contrary to many European countries, work insertion, domestic help, daycare, and multi-stakeholder organizations already have a legal social economy basis, namely as cooperatives, including solidarity co-ops, and nonprofit associations. Also, the Québec law on cooperatives is very explicit about strict abidance to specified principles, namely democratic governance by members and profit distribution limitation principles. By and large, the terms "social enterprise" and "social entrepreneurship," when used by the English-speaking community and in the business schools of both the Québec English- and French-speaking communities, refer to nonprofit organizations that commercialize their activities. This basically corresponds to the definition included in the Québec Social Economy Act.
The definition of social enterprise proposed by EMES also includes other legal statuses, such as private capitalist enterprises, if they meet a set of criteria. In Europe, "labels" were in some cases created to formalize the existence these hybrid forms of enterprises, such as the "community interest companies" in the United Kingdom and the Belgian "sociétés à finalité sociale." As Québec does not have a specific legal status or a label for these kinds of organizations, the latter would, in Québec, be grouped together with other existent and traditional legal statuses of enterprises, including those of social economy enterprises when applicable.
Thus, certain types of enterprises that are recognized as aiming at a social goal are still understudied and have yet to be properly categorized into a typology. Based on this general overview of the social economy and the social enterprise concept in Québec, the next section explores these issues, proposing a framework for classifying social economy enterprises in Québec in relation to the notion of social enterprise.
A PROPOSED FRAMEWORK FOR SOCIAL ECONOMY ENTERPRISES IN QUÉBEC
Québec, as was previously discussed, has an established legal framework for social economy enterprises that recognizes three main legal forms: cooperatives, mutual societies, and associations. But there are also organizations that are identified, by themselves or by researchers, as taking part in the Québec social economy, while not sharing its core institutional characteristics. Others still are in fact part of the social economy, as it is institutionally defined, but are named differently, on account of their innovative dynamics or of the language used (English versus French). A social economy framework should provide a broad conceptual basis for understanding the field as a whole.
We propose to refer to the four core distinguishing empirical features of social economy organizations, as identified by the Québec Social Economy Act and summarized by Bouchard, Cyrille Ferraton, and Valérie Michaud (2008) and Bouchard, Cruz Filho & St-Denis (2011): democratic governance; restricted or prohibited distribution of surplus; autonomy and independence from the state; and the organized production of goods or services that serve mutual or general interest objectives. These characteristics are usually institutionalized by rules or bylaws.4 Just one feature alone would be insufficient to capture the essence of the social economy, and none of the features has precedence over any other. Instead, it takes a combination of these characteristics to define a social economy enterprise. These features integrate the social purpose of the enterprise into concrete rules of behaviour, and the degree to which they are embedded in legal frameworks gives them stability in the long run. Figure 1 illustrates these features, showing that it is through them that these organizations perform an economic activity to the benefit of its social purpose, and that they likely will perpetuate their social mission over time.
In theory, each of these criteria could be found in other legal forms of enterprises, in a more or less institutionalized manner, going from ad hoc behaviours (such as in corporate social responsibility) to internal or external rules that guarantee the perpetuation of the principle over time. In addition, if enterprises were to be considered as social enterprises on the sole account of their purpose (as proposed by authors such as Austin, 2004; Boschee, 1995; Dees, 2001; Drayton & MacDonald, 1993), then the purpose would be a sufficient criterion. That said, one would still need to delve into the different definitions of "social purpose" and the normative meanings they may carry.
The above exploration suggests a framework for analyzing social enterprises as a larger whole. This framework, which is well adapted to the Québec Social Economy Act (Québec, 2013), aims to qualify social enterprises according to how they correspond to organizational features. Organizational features, such as organized economic activity, limited distribution, democratic governance, and autonomy and independence, make it possible to distinguish social economy enterprises from all other types of organizations in the economy (Bouchard, Cruz Filho, & St-Denis, 2011). To include organizations that do not operate with those organizational features, purpose features can be considered as a further distinguishing feature. According to the Institut du Nouveau Monde, for example, one such purpose feature could be an innovative entrepreneurial response to social needs that is participatory with the community, is ethical and promotes social change, and leads to sustainable social benefits. Such distinction is also what is sought by applying the labels of "B Corp" as in the US, "social utility" as in France or Belgium, or "social action" as in Spain.
The framework therefore enables to identify three categories in which social enterprises exist, by applying three successive filters (see Figure 2):
A. Enterprises that are constrained by law or other rules to perpetuate their societal purpose through their social economy organizational features. These are the typical social economy enterprises and comprise the core of the social economy. For these organizations, the social economy principles are strongly institutionalized by the application of rules and laws, and can be reinforced by public policy. Some examples in Québec are social economy childcare centres, domestic help social economy enterprises, work integration enterprises, and solidarity cooperatives.
B. Enterprises that correspond to organizational features of the social economy, as defined in the Québec Social Economy Act, but do not share the same institutionalized legal statuses as the category A organizations. This corresponds to the inclusive social economy movement or social economy periphery-larger than how the Social Economy Act defines it. This category comprises two kinds of organizations. First, share-holders' for-profit subsidiaries of typical social economy enterprises, which are borderline cases that can be placed at the frontier of categories B and C, because they can be structured in a for-profit organizational form but be owned by a typical social economy enterprise. Second, peripheral organizations are those that "take part" in the social economy, even if they do not meet all the criteria announced.
C. Economic private entities with a societal purpose that do not necessarily have institutionalized rules that guarantee the perpetuation of their mission or their organizational features (excluding corporate social responsibility).
It is also possible to identify two other cross-sectional categories of social enterprises in such a framework (see Figure 2). The cross-sectional categories (D and E) were identified for clarification purposes and will not be further explored in this report:
D. Mixed holdings, which comprise a corporation with one or more social enterprises of the three categories described above. An example is Cirque du Soleil, which is a corporate organization that also includes a nonprofit organization dedicated to the diffusion of circus arts (Tohu) and a private foundation aiming at fighting poverty by providing access to water and sanitation in developing countries (One Drop).
E. Networks of social enterprises that can be also comprised of any of the three or four modalities described above. An example is CAP Finance, which is a network of solidarity finance organizations in Québec. It is composed of a typical institutionalized social enterprise (La Caisse d'économie solidaire Desjardins) and social economic periphery representatives (La Fiducie du Chantier de l'Économie sociale, Filaction, Fondaction, Le Fonds de solidarité FTQ, Le Réseau d'investissement social du Québec and Le Réseau québécois du crédit communautaire).
THREE CATEGORIES TO MAP THE FIELD IN QUÉBEC
This section describes the characteristics of the three categories that help understand social economy versus other types of "social enterprises" in Québec from the proposed framework above. In the following, we will present some exemplary cases in order to illustrate each category.
Institutionalized social economy
The institutionalized social economy category covers social enterprises that are characterized by the typical social economy principles and rules. They represent the core of the main features of typical EMES social enterprises and of Québec's typical social economy organizations. Some examples in Québec that are close to the EMES definition of a social enterprise are:
* CPEs (centres de la petite enfance/childcare centres) are nonprofit organizations (NPOs) or cooperatives, in which at least two thirds of the board of directors is parents of children who attend or will attend the childcare centre. A CPE offers reduced-contribution places (currently at $7 a day) to seven or more children, and is largely financed by the state.
* EÉSADs (entreprises d'économie sociale en aide domestique/domestic help social economy enterprises) are NPOs or cooperatives that were created to provide domestic help services to elderly and disabled people who are in the process of losing their autonomy and at the same time legally regularize the jobs in this sector, avoiding unreported employment. EÉSADs have mixed revenues, combining market and non-market sources. The latter are provided by a public policy named Programme d'exonération financière en services à domicile (PEFSAD).
* WISEs (work integration social enterprises) in Québec are NPOs with the main objective of socially and economically integrating disadvantaged and excluded people into the workforce. They also have mixed revenues sources and are supported by a public policy specially created for them. While some cooperatives may also have a work integration mission, they cannot be included in the Québec work insertion government program. They can be, however, recognized by government as "adapted work enterprises" if they employ people with physical or mental disabilities.
* Solidarity cooperatives are multi-stakeholder cooperatives composed of at least two and up to three categories of members: users of the services provided by the cooperative; workers working within the organization; and supporting members. Supporting members can be persons or organizations that share and support the cooperative's mission. This combination allows the emergence of a joint construction of supply and demand. An example is the Coopérative DesÉquilibres, a solidarity cooperative devoted to youth sports and social involvement, which is also mentioned by INM as an "inspiring example" of social entrepreneurship, under its À go, on change le monde program.
* The Québec Social Economy Act also covers the more established cooperatives such as the Caisses populaires Desjardins (credit unions), mutual societies such as the Groupe Promutuel in the insurance sector, and nonprofit organizations such as the many housing cooperatives and associations.
Social economy periphery or inclusive social economy movement
Two types of organizations belong to category "B" described above, that is, the social economy periphery or comprehensive movement. The first type is composed of subsidiaries of social economy enterprises, which sometimes have complex structures, including entities under their control, be it partial or full. We define a subsidiary as "a company in which the reporting entity owns a majority (more than 50%) of the voting shares" (Statistics Canada, 2011). The focus is on subsidiaries of social economy enterprises that are not themselves social economy enterprises (individual enterprises, stock corporations, partnership corporations, etc.). Some examples in Québec are Iögo (owned by the agro food cooperative Agropour), Desjardins Capital de risque (owned by Desjardins credit unions), and Auberge L'Autre Jardin (owned by a non-governmental organization, Carrefour Tiers Monde). These subsidiaries can be considered as being part of the social economy if they meet the following criteria (Bouchard, Cruz Filho & St-Denis, 2011):
* The majority control of the subsidiary belongs to the social economy enterprise or a set of social economy enterprises that are direct or indirect (through a holding company) shareholders of the subsidiary. When ownership is shared with organizations that are not social economy enterprises, the following indicators can be:
* The majority of board seats are reserved for the social economy enterprise (or a set of social economy enterprises).
* If there is a general meeting, a majority of votes must be given to the social economy enterprise (or the set of social economy enterprises).
* The activity of the subsidiary, in the case of cooperatives or mutual societies, is linked to the activities of the members. In the case of associations, it is linked to the activities of users and recipients of goods or services.
* The profits of the subsidiary that are not reinvested in the activities of the subsidiary are distributed to the controlling social economy enterprise(s), proportionally to the capital held (which may not be less than 50 percent).
The second type is composed of "peripheral organizations" (see Figure 3). The social economy field can be described, at least from a conceptual point of view, as composed of entities that form its "core," as well as of "peripheral" entities (Desroche, 1983). There is a general consensus that some organizations "take part" in the social economy even if they do not meet all the criteria enounced in the Québec Social Economy Act. The Fiducie du Chantier de l'économie sociale (a financial trust dedicated to the social economy), Fondaction CSN (a union fund dedicated to job creation and sustainable development), or Centraide du Grand Montréal (a public foundation where volunteers collect and allocate the funds to community based organizations) are examples of this type. In those cases, it suffices that the organizations meet only some of those criteria, namely in accordance with rules, laws, or internal bylaws (Bouchard, 2013).
* Social economy trust funds such as the Fiducie du Chantier perform an activity that may not be considered as a "production" activity, but they do not distribute profits; they have a collective, democratic, and autonomous governance; and they are dedicated to the social economy, therefore producing a collective service and acting as a countervailing power in the market.
* Worker unions' funds (e.g., Fondaction and Fonds de solidarité FTQ) have a share capital ownership structure but operate with a participatory structure. Their investments aim to reinforce the comparative advantages of economic sectors while at the same time maintain and develop employment as well as foster sustainable development. They therefore produce a collective service and act as a countervailing power in the market. Some consider these funds as fully-fledged social economy actors (Lévesque, 2013).
* Community foundations, such as Centraide du Grand Montréal (United Way), have highly participative structures that contribute to the alleviation of poverty in a democratic fashion, therefore producing a collective service or credence good. Volunteers not only participate in fundraising but also in fund allocation. Sometimes such foundations develop a community-based approach in joint ventures with government, such as the participation of Fondation Lucie et André Chagnon in "Québec Avenir d'enfants."
* Local exchange trading systems (LETS), such as Accorderies, Troc-tes-trucs, and The Swap Team, are mostly or entirely based on non-monetary resources. They produce a service and do not distribute profits. They also have a social mission and a democratic and autonomous governance. They function under the economic principle of gift exchange and reciprocity (Polanyi, 1944).
* Some of yesterday's community-based private initiatives are today's government-supported organizations, such as youth employment centres, and remain governed democratically by a board composed of a mixed group of people.
* Some NPOs, such as arts or cultural organizations, are engaged in activities that have a large impact on communities without democratically mobilizing a large number of members.
These examples show that the scope of the social economy movement is in fact quite large, and yet precise criteria are nevertheless needed to define it and the organizations that belong to it. In the following, we will explain in detail how social economy criteria can help understand why such organizations are considered as participating in the social economy and, hence, could be considered as "social enterprises."
Social purpose enterprises
An enlarged view of this perspective would also include for-profit entrepreneurs of social or environmental causes, which do not necessarily have institutionalized rules that ensure the perpetuation of their mission or organizational features. Some are traditional single-ownership for-profit enterprises that get involved in high-profile social or environmental missions. The founders of those enterprises are accordingly referred to as "social entrepreneurs" by the INM. Some of the Ashoka projects are also considered to be social purpose enterprises. These projects must meet five criteria: a new idea, creativity, entrepreneurial quality, ethical fibre, and the social impact of the idea. This last criterion "focuses on the systems change of the candidate's idea, not the candidate. Ashoka is only interested in ideas that it believes will change the field significantly and that will trigger nationwide impact or, for smaller countries, broader regional change. For example, Ashoka will not support the launch of a new school or clinic unless it is part of a broader strategy to reform the education or health system at the national level and beyond" (Ashoka, 2015). Some examples in Québec are:
* Communauto (founded in 1994): "Since its founding in 1994, Communauto is seen as a pioneer in America as the oldest and one of the largest car-sharing services on this side of the Atlantic. One of the largest companies of its kind in the world, Communauto is defined primarily as a business with a social and environmental mission. Car-sharing is a cheaper and more flexible alternative than ownership and renting. Our objective is to offer a convenient and economical alternative to car ownership. Communauto thereby contributes to reduce both the number and the use of automobiles" (Communauto, 2015, our translation).
* Lufa Farms (founded in 2009): "In 2011, we built the world's first commercial rooftop greenhouse. Through innovation and technology, we are striving to change the way cities eat. Our concept is simple: grow food where people live and grow it more sustainably" (Lufa Farms, 2014).
* Takt-etik (founded in 2006): Certified as a B-Corp. "In a world where sustainability and corporate social responsibility are starting to become mainstream business practices and where actions speak louder than words, Takt-etik guides its clients to successfully embark on this process. Takt-etik relies on the expertise of eight advisors that have a combined 25 years of sustainability consulting experience, making it the largest firm of its kind in Québec. Takt-etik also relies on a network of partners to support its clients on specific needs such as water and energy management" (Takt-etik, 2010).
* Invup (founded in 2011): "Invup.com is an online platform helping businesses and schools to manage their volunteer programs and donations" (Forces Avenir, 2011).
* E-180.com is a private company website that encourages people to meet in order to exchange knowledge: "E-180 stems from the hard-held belief that all humans possess the power to develop their full potential autonomously, with a little help from their community. We believe that education is a relationship, not an institution, and that one hour of our time may change another person's life. Our mission is to promote these values by helping fellow humans share knowledge and connect with each other" (E-180, 2015).
CONCLUSION
The concept of the "social economy enterprise" in Québec shares many of the characteristics of the concept of "social enterprise" adopted by EMES. An important difference is that the EMES definition is an ideal-type proposed for research purposes, whereas the institutionalized definition of the social economy in Québec reflects a broad consensus among social actors in a given institutional context. Another important difference is that the EMES definition covers for-profit share-capital enterprises whereas the Québec definition only includes statutory social economy enterprises. Still, the dynamics that characterize the emergence of the new social economy in Québec offer an interesting perspective for digging into the questions raised by the ICSEM project regarding social enterprise models and their institutionalization.
Because Québec has a highly institutionalized definition of social economy enterprises (e.g., Cooperatives Act, Social Economy Act, Community Action Framework) and of some of their specific fields of activities (daycare, domestic help, work insertion, employment for the disabled, youth employment centres, community economic development corporations, etc.), the use of the term "social enterprise" has been scarce. However, the field of the social economy is a changing one. Certain sectors that have long since been a part of the social economy may no longer feel they fit the new understanding of the social economy (e.g., credit unions, farmers' cooperatives). Or, some large social economy enterprises may be regarded as part of this field but may not appreciate that they could be regarded as part of it (e.g., longstanding and previously religious social organizations such the YMCAs). Social actors recognize still others, but who do not meet all the criteria stipulated in the law (e.g., community foundations, workers unions' funds, cooperatives, or NPO-owned shareholders corporations, etc.). Some want to be a part of the social economy but only fit the social or environmental purpose criteria without meeting any of the organizational traits (e.g., Communauto, Lufa Farms). In addition, new hybrids are emerging that have dynamics that combine philanthropy, entrepreneurship, and government aid (e.g., Québec Avenir d'enfants). Hence, the notion of social enterprise might be relevant at some point in order to capture those changing features of the field. But the risks associated with a view of "social enterprises" or "social entrepreneurship" as anything and everything has so far led most of the Québec social economy actors to use the terms of social economy, new social economy, or collective enterprises.
In our view, to develop a framework for a typology of social enterprises in Québec, two steps must be accomplished. The first step is to identify empirical qualifying criteria for organizations that can be considered by the institutional definition in place. In Québec, where a highly institutionalized definition of the social economy is already in place, institutionalization is understood to refer not only to public recognition but also to mutual and societal recognition by the social actors themselves. Our qualification criteria should thus be aligned with this consensual definition. In a second step, using these criteria, the exceptions, borderline cases, and new developments can then be identified and described. For example, the notion of social entrepreneurship, which is slowly gaining currency in Québec, could serve as a starting point for defining commercial ventures that are marketed by their social purpose. Such a qualification framework can serve as the basis for a typology.
The proposed typology for Québec identifies three types of social enterprises. The first category includes only those enterprises recognized by the Québec Social Economy Act, which have institutionalized all the criteria of the social economy. The second category covers all enterprises that are closely linked to the social economy sector, pursue a societal mission, and adopt, in an institutionalized manner (law, rule, bylaw) some features of the social economy as defined in Québec. This includes subsidiaries of institutionalized social economy enterprises, as well as peripheral organizations of the social economy movement. The third type, large and inclusive, covers all enterprises that pursue a societal (social or environmental) mission, notwithstanding their organizational features or modes of production. It is important to note that many social actors and academics in Québec consider the perimeter to be limited to either the social economy periphery or movement or to institutionalized social economy organizations, in other words, to collective or community-based enterprises (as defined in Lévesque, 2002).
Some organizations that are characterized by Québec's social economy principles and rules also represent the core features that describe the typical EMES social enterprise, as they are characterized by institutional and organizational social innovations. It is the case with the domestic help social economy enterprise (EÉSAD, entreprises d'économie sociale d'aide domestique). On the institutional side, the EÉSAD model combines new forms of mobilization by marginalized actors and new modes of financing in order to answer unmet domestic services needs with workers who were excluded from the labour market (Jetté, Aubry, & Vaillancourt, 2006), hence serving general interest goals. Public policy was co-constructed by social actors and public administration, which also represents an institutional innovation. On the organizational side, EÉSADs allow the participation of different kinds of stakeholders, users/clients, and employees in the production and use of domestic services.
One of the main contributions of the typology proposed in this article is the introduction of a new starting point for the development and description of types of social enterprises. Usually, typologies are defined broadly and then gradually narrowed to identify social enterprises. The proposed typology does the reverse, starting at the heart of social economy and then adding additional layers for identifying other types of social enterprises. We believe that such a methodology could be a first step in the effort to develop typologies that are based primarily on social economy concepts and principles.
As Alex Nicholls (2010) noted, research on social enterprises and social entrepreneurship is still at a pre-paradigmatic stage, and its progression to a post-paradigmatic stage "can be understood as a contested process of legitimization between different actors, discourses and institutional logics" (p. 614). In this article, we have presented the concept of the social economy that is used in Québec as a result of a broad consensus between a wide range of social actors including cooperatives, local development groups, worker unions, community groups, feminist, environmental, rural, and urban social movements, and government. Of late, the concepts of social enterprise and social entrepreneurship are also increasingly in use by actors coming from Anglo-Saxon business schools and from business philanthropy, but not exclusively. Further research should involve digging deeper into the discourse of these sets of actors and examining the institutional logics on which they are based. This would advance our understanding of what is at stake in terms of organizational models, paths of institutionalization, and development paradigms.
NOTES
1. The legal framework in which most nonprofit organizations incorporate in Québec is very loose (Part 3 of the Companies' Act), and many have nothing to do with social economy principles.
2. Professor Steve McGuire, in private conversation with author at the launch of the initiative.
3. See: http://www.bcorporation.net/community/find-a-b-corp?search=Québec.
4. A study conducted for Human Resources and Skills Development Canada by Statistics Canada (McDougall, 2007) demonstrated that, out of a probabilistic sample of the Canadian Business Registry, enterprises other than cooperatives, nonprofits, or mutual societies that adopted features characteristic of the social economy (as defined in Bouchard et al., 2006, and reiterated in Bouchard, Cruz Filho, & St-Denis, 2011are statistically absent.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
The authors would like to thank Jacques Defourny and Benoît Lévesque as well as the blind reviewers for their insightful comments and suggestions on previous versions of this article.
WEBSITES
Ashoka: Innovators for the Public. (2015). http://www.ashoka.org
Ashoka Canada: Everyone a changemaker. (2015). http://www.canada.ashoka.org
Chaire de recherche du Canada en économie sociale. (2015). http://www.chaire.ecosoc.uqam.ca/
Communauto. (2015). http://www.communauto.com
E-180. (2015). http://www.e-180.com
Forces avenir. (2015) http://www.forcesavenir.qc.ca
Institut du Nouveau Monde. (2015). http://www.inm.qc.ca
Lufa Farms. (2015). http://lufa.com/en/
Takt-etik. (2015). http://takt-etik.com
REFERENCES
Austin, J.E., various authors, & the SEKN team. (2004). Social partnering in Latin America. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University.
Boschee, J. (1995). Social entrepreneurship. Across the board. 32(3), 20-25.
Bouchard, M.J. (2013). Mémoire sur la loi de l'économie sociale. Submission to the Ministère des Affaires municipales et de l'Occupation du territoire, upon invitation to participate in the hearings of the Parliamentary Committee, Québec, National Assembly. URL http://www.chaire.ecosoc.uqam.ca/ Portals/ChaireEcoSoc/ChaireEcoSoc_M%C3%A9moireProjetLoi27.pdf [May 28, 2015].
Bouchard, M.J., Ferraton, C., & Michaud, V. (2008). First steps of an information system on the social economy: Qualifying the organizations. Estudios de Economía Aplicada, 26(1), 7-24.
Bouchard, M. J., Cruz Filho, P., & St-Denis, M. (2011). Cadre conceptuel pour définir la population statistique de l'économie sociale au Québec. Montréal, QC: Chaire de recherche du Canada en économie sociale, Collection Recherche, no R-2011-02.
Bouchard, M.J., & Hudon, M. (2008). Se loger autrement au Québec. Le mouvement de l'habitat communautaire, un acteur du développement social et économique. Montréal, QC: Éditions Albert St-Martin.
Comeau, Y. (1996). Guide de collecte et de catégorisation des données pour l'étude d'activités de l'économie sociales. Collection Études théoriques, no ET9605. Montréal, QC : Centre de recherche sur les innovations sociales, Cahiers du CRISES.
Comeau, Y., Boucher, J.L., Malo, M.-C., & Vaillancourt, Y. (2001). Essai de typologie des entreprises de l'économie sociale et solidaire. Cahiers du CRISES, Collection Études théoriques, no ET0117. Montréal, QC : Centre de recherche sur les innovations sociales.
Dees, J.G. (2001). The meaning of social entrepreneurship. Kauffman Center for Entrepreneurial Leadership and Miriam and Peter Haas Centennial Professor in Public Service. Reformatted and revised from original published in 1998. URL: http://csi.gsb.stanford.edu/sites/csi.gsb.stanford.edu/files/ TheMeaningofsocialEntrepreneurship.pdf [accessed June 1, 2015].
Defourny, J., & Nyssens, M. (2006). Defining social enterprise. In M. Nyssens (Ed.), Social enterprise: At the crossroads of market, public policies and civil society (pp. 3-26). London, UK: Routledge.
Defourny, J., & Nyssens, M. (2011). Approches européennes et américaines de l'entreprise sociale: une perspective comparative. Recma, Revue Internationale de l'économie sociale, 319, 18-36.
Desroche, H. (1983). Pour un traité d'économie sociale. Paris, FR: Coopérative d'information et d'édition mutualiste.
Drayton, W., & MacDonald, S. (1993). Leading public entrepreneurs. Arlington, VA: Ashoka - Innovators for the Public.
Enjolras, B. (2000). Coordination failure, property rights and non-profit organizations. Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 71(3), 347-374.
Fontan, J.-M. (2011). Entreprenariat social et entreprenariat collectif: synthèse et constats. Canadian Journal of Nonprofit and Social Economy Research/Revue Canadienne de recherche sur les OSBL et l'économie sociale, 2(2), 37-56.
Fontan, J.-M., Lévesque, B., & Charbonneau, M. (2011). Les fondations privées québécoises, un champ de recherche émergent. Lien social et politique, 65, 43-64.
Forces Avenir (2011). Avenir entrepreneuriat, affaires et vie économique (2015). URL: http://www .forcesavenir.qc.ca/universitaire/finaliste_view/3349 [June 1, 2015].
Gazzoli, P., Jetté, D., Chamberland, V., Dumais, L., & Vaillancourt, Y. (2014). Nouvel essor des fondations au Québec et au Canada : Pour une analyse sociopolitique fondée sur le concept d'économie plurielle. Annales de l'économie publique, sociale et coopérative, 85(2), 165-191.
Hannan, M.T., & Freeman, J.H. (1989). Organizational ecology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Institut du Nouveau Monde (2015). Concours À go, on change le monde! 2015. URL : http://www.francosourd .com/profiles/blogs/concours-a-go-on-change-le-monde-2015 [June 1, 2015].
Jetté, C., Aubry, F., & Vaillancourt, Y. (2006). L'économie sociale dans les services à domicile : une innovation davantage institutionnelle qu'organisationnelle. Économie et solidarités, 36(2), 129-151.
Laville, J.-L. (2007). Économie et solidarité : esquisse d'une problématique. In J.-L. Laville (Ed.), L'économie solidaire, Une perspective internationale (pp. 9-76). Paris, FR: Hachette Littératures.
Lévesque, B. (2002). Entrepreneurship collectif et économie sociale : entreprendre autrement. Montréal, QC : Alliances de recherche universités-communautés en économie sociale, no I-02-2002. URL : http://www.aruc-es.uqam.ca/Portals/0/cahiers/I-02-2002.pdf [accessed June 1, 2015].
Lévesque, B. (2003). Mondialisation, démocratie plurielle, économie sociale et solidaire. Économie et Solidarités, Hors série, 103-121.
Lévesque, B. (2011). Innovations sociales et pouvoirs publics : vers un système québécois d'innovation dédié à l'économie sociale et solidaire. Quelques éléments de problématique. Montréal, QC : Centre de recherche sur les innovations sociales, Cahiers du CRISES, Collection Études théoriques, no ET1106.
Lévesque, B. (2013). How the social economy won recognition in Québec at the end of the 20th century. In M.-J. Bouchard (Ed.), Innovation and the social economy: The Québec experience (pp. 25-70). Toronto, ON: University of Toronto Press.
McDougall, B. (2007). Results of the 2006 feasability study on the for-profit segment of the community sector [internal report]. Ottawa, ON: Human Resources and Skills Development Canada.
Mendell, M. (2010). Reflections on the evolving landscape of social enterprise in North America. Policy and Society, 29, 243-256.
Nicholls, A. (2010). The legitimacy of social entrepreneurship: Reflexive isomorphism in a pre-paradigmatic field. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 34(4), 611-633.
Polanyi, K. (1944). The great transformation: The political and economic origins of our time. Boston, MA: Beacon Press.
Québec. (2013). Loi sur l'économie sociale. Québec, QC: Éditeur Officiel du Québec. URL : http://www2 .publicationsduquebec.gouv.qc.ca/dynamicSearch/telecharge.php?type=5&file=2013C22F.PDF [accessed June 1, 2015].
Rousselière, D., & Bouchard, M.J. (2011), À propos de l'hétérogénéité des formes organisationnelles de l'économie sociale : isomorphisme vs écologie des organisations en économie sociale. Revue canadienne de sociologie, 48(4), 414-453.
Spear, R. (2011). Formes coopératives hybrides. Recma, Revue Internationale de l'économie sociale, 320, 26-42.
Statistics Canada. (2011). Reporting guide for balance of payments questionnaires. URL: http://www23.statcan .gc.ca/imdb-bmdi/pub/document/1534_D8_T1_V2-eng.htm [May 28, 2015].
Marie J. Bouchard, Paulo Cruz Filho, & Tassadit Zerdani
Université du Québec à Montréal
ABOUT THE AUTHORS / LES AUTEURS
Marie J. Bouchard is Professor at the École des sciences de la gestion (ESG) at l'Université du Québec à Montréal (UQAM) and chairs the Collective Enterprises' Axis of the Centre de recherche sur les innovations sociales (CRISES). Email: [email protected] .
Paulo Cruz Filho is Professor of Strategy at FAE Business School (Brazil) and a PhD candidate in Administration at the École des sciences de la gestion (ESG) at l'Université du Québec à Montréal (UQAM). Email: [email protected] .
Tassadit Zerdani is Research Professional at the École des sciences de la gestion (ESG) at Université du Québec à Montréal (UQAM) and a PhD candidate in Administration at the École des sciences de la gestion (ESG) at l'Université du Québec à Montréal (UQAM). Email: [email protected] .
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer
Copyright Association for Nonprofit and Social Economy Research Spring 2015