This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
1. Introduction
In recent years, the trend of global warming has further intensified and has gradually become one of the hot spots of international concern. The development of a low-carbon economy has become one of the major strategic initiatives to promote the sustainable development of the global economy. Many countries have successively introduced a series of policies such as carbon tax, cap-and-trade, and low carbon subsidy policy. In such a global green revolution, consumers are increasingly aware of low-carbon consumption. In order to cope with the pressure from the government and the market, manufacturing companies have proposed carbon emission reduction strategies in the supply chain: first, to increase the transformation and upgrading of the company’s carbon emission reduction technology; second, to put forward emission reduction requirements for upstream and downstream suppliers. However, the high level of carbon emission reduction target will undoubtedly increase the operating cost of the entire supply chain, thereby reducing the operational performance of the supply chain. Therefore, it is necessary to study the emission reduction level of supply chain.
The carbon tax policy has been continuously valued by countries all over the world for its simplicity and operability. Carbon tax can limit the total amount of corporate emissions to a given range, which will facilitate companies to change their supply chain management modes, thereby reducing carbon emissions across the supply chain [1]. However, as a means of taxation, carbon tax will inevitably bring additional costs to manufacturing companies, which will have a negative impact on the supply chain operation process [2, 3] and also restrict the emission reduction level of companies.
With the deepening of the global green revolution, consumers’ low-carbon preferences are increasing. In order to gain more market share, manufacturing companies will continue to meet market demand through technological innovation of emission reduction. However, technological innovation driven by excessive emission reduction level will increase the production cost of unit product, thus reducing the market competitiveness of products. At the same time, due to uncertainties such as emission reduction technology update, replacement product introduction, and changes in consumer demand, the market demand for products under corporate emission reduction conditions shows higher randomness, and the operational risk of emission reduction companies will be further aggravated when the cost per unit product increases. However, there are certain interaction effects between carbon tax, consumer’s low-carbon preferences, and carbon emission reduction: on the one hand, carbon tax will increase the operating cost of companies, while consumers’ low-carbon preferences will increase the market demand of low-carbon products and further affect the retail price; on the other hand, to some extent, carbon emission reduction will reduce the cost of carbon tax in supply chain and increase consumers’ preference for products, but it will generate emission reduction costs [4, 5]. In summary, this paper argues that the following issues need to be determined.
(1) Under stochastic market demand, how do we set the emission reduction level of the supply chain when considering the interaction effect of carbon tax and consumers’ low-carbon preferences?
(2) What effect does carbon tax and consumers’ preferences have on revenue sharing contracts between supply chain members?
In view of this, this paper first constructs a price function of retail price on consumers’ low-carbon preferences and emission reduction level. Based on the penalty mechanism and reverse derivation method, it determines the revenue models of the retailer and the manufacturer when the supply chain reduces emissions or not under stochastic demand and conducts a comparative study from the perspective of decentralized and centralized decision-making. Furthermore, the optimal emission reduction level of supply chain based on carbon tax and consumers’ low-carbon preference under stochastic demand is determined by mathematical modeling, and the relationship between parameters is simulated and analyzed by MATLAB. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 proposes research questions on the basis of literature review. Section 3 derives the supply chain members’ revenue models for decentralized and centralized supply chain under the condition of supply chain emission reduction and nonemission reduction. In Section 4, we determine the optimal emission reduction level based on carbon tax and consumers’ low-carbon preferences under stochastic demand through mathematical modeling. In Section 5, we explore the dynamic relationship among decision parameters through simulation analysis. Furthermore, we conclude our research findings in Section 6 with closing remarks.
2. Literature Review
The literature reviewed here mainly involves three research directions: (i) carbon tax policy and carbon emission reduction; (ii) supply chain emission reduction decision-making, operational mechanism and cooperation; (iii) consumers’ low carbon preferences and supply chain emission reduction.
Carbon tax, as a kind of emission reduction measures with extremely high market efficiency, has been widely used in developed countries and regions. Marron and Toder [6] believed that an effective carbon tax policy can reduce the risk of climate change, minimize the cost of emission reduction, promote the innovation of low-carbon technology, and increase the public revenue of society. Metcalf [7] emphasized that a key factor in using carbon taxes to reduce emissions is the reasonable pricing of greenhouse gas emissions. Chen and Hao [8] found that when a company incurs a higher carbon tax, it will receive a higher percentage of carbon emission reduction, and the carbon tax policy has a greater impact on the carbon reduction of low-efficiency company. Xiang and Lawley [9] found that the carbon tax in British Columbia (BC) significantly reduced the natural gas consumption of local residents by approximately 7%. Ding, Zhang and Song [10] argued that the increase in carbon taxes could accelerate the spread of energy technologies and significantly reduce carbon discharges peak value. For the economic effect of the carbon tax, Gros et al. [2] thought that the carbon tax will increase the cost of transformation for energy-intensive industries, which in turn will reduce GDP. Liu and Lu [11] believed that the government could reduce the carbon tax collection cost in a disguised manner by reducing production tax and consumption tax, which would be beneficial to the adjustment of the economic structure and the improvement of continuous emission reduction. Xie et al. [3] found that the implementation of carbon tax had a slight negative impact on the economic growth of Chongqing in China. Due to the different geographical location, industrial structure, energy structure, and other characteristics, the impacts of carbon tax on the level of economic activity in different regions are different. Zhao et al. [12] found that when the carbon tax reaches 30 yuan/ton or the free quota of carbon dioxide is less than 50%, Chinese investors prefer wind power generation to coal-fired power generation.
Supply chain emission reduction has become a hot issue in the theoretical and practical fields. In terms of the carbon emission reduction decision-making, Du et al. [13] found that market risk affects carbon emission reduction, while Tao et al. [14] argued that different supply chain forms, such as closed-loop supply chains, also have an impact on carbon emission reduction. Luo et al. [15] found that, under the cap-and-trade policy, coopetition will bring more profits and less total carbon emissions to the two manufacturers. Rao et al. [16] suggested that changes in carbon tax will have an impact on the optimal choice of emission reductions, and, with the increase of carbon tax, carbon emission reductions will present a nonlinear emission reduction trend. Cao et al. [17] studied the impacts of cap-and-trade policy (CTP) and low carbon subsidy policy (LCSP) on manufacturer’s production and carbon emission reduction level and believed that the carbon emission reduction level increases with the increase in carbon trading price and has nothing to do with the unit low carbon subsidy. Madani and Rasti-Barzoki [18] established a game model for the government providing emission reduction subsidies and carbon tax and analyzed the impact of government fiscal and taxation policies on the optimal emission reduction decisions in the supply chain. For the carbon reduction mechanisms, Drake et al. [19] argue that when a company has a mix of clean and nonclean technologies, investment and subsidies increase the expected emissions to some extent, but do not affect a company’s optimal capacity. Fahimnia et al. [20] proposed the way to price carbon for maximum environmental revenue per dollar increase in supply chain cost, which makes it easy for the company to make trade-offs from emission costs. Chen et al. [21] studied the optimal pricing and unit carbon emissions decisions of two manufacturers under the balanced and imbalanced power structures. It was found that, under the balanced power structure, the higher the efficiency of carbon emission reduction, the greater the manufacturer’s output and the more investment in green technology. For supply chain cooperation in carbon reduction, Benjaafar et al. [22] argued that it is possible to effectively reduce carbon emissions through operational adjustments and collaboration with supply chain members without significantly increasing costs. Ghosh and Shah [23] found that when supply chain members use cost-sharing contracts for cooperation, the emission reduction level and benefits will be affected by the cost of abatement and consumers’ low-carbon preferences. Yu and Han [24] adopted two types of contracts, i.e., the modified wholesale price (MW) and the modified cost-sharing contract (MS), and achieved supply chain coordination, which will promote the supply chain efficiency, but will not bring additional benefits to the manufacturer.
To a certain extent, consumers’ low-carbon preferences will promote companies to reduce emissions and improve emission reduction technologies. For the role of consumers’ low-carbon preferences in reducing emissions, Wang, Zhao & He [5] argued that higher consumer’s low-carbon preferences will improve the retailer’s position in the supply chain revenue sharing contract negotiations, which in turn will enhance the overall emission reduction level of the supply chain. Shewmake et al. [25] found that if consumers are more sensitive to goods with carbon labels, then the value of their individual carbon footprint will be higher, and the simulation results showed that consumers’ low-carbon preferences have a more significant effect on carbon emission reduction of alcohol and meat. Xia et al. [26] found that the improvement of consumers’ low-carbon awareness encourages supply chain members to invest in emission reduction, which is beneficial to their profits and utilities. For the impact of low-carbon preferences on corporate earnings, Liuabc [27] thought that the increase of consumers’ low-carbon preferences will have an impact on the competitive results of supply chain members, but if the cost of abatement does not have an advantage, the profitability of eco-friendly companies will tend to decline. Shuai et al. [28] considered that the education level and monthly income of consumers are the main factors for their purchase of low-carbon products, so consumer choice is the key to determining the benefits of low-carbon products of the manufacturer. Du et al. [13] constructed an emission-sensitive demand function considering consumers’ low-carbon preferences and analyzed the impact of low-carbon preferences on market demand and supply chain members’ returns.
For the issue of supply chain emission reduction, the previous literatures did not consider the effects of market stochastic demand, carbon tax, and consumers’ low-carbon preferences simultaneously. Moreover, when constructing the revenue model of supply chain, the retail price is usually regarded as a constant, ignoring the dynamic effects of carbon emissions and other factors on the retail price, which is inconsistent with the reality [13, 18, 22]. In view of this, the main innovations of this paper are as follows. Firstly, it constructs a function of retail price on consumers’ low-carbon preferences and emission reduction level. Secondly, introducing the emission reduction penalty mechanism and adopting the reverse derivation method, it derives revenue models of the retailer and the manufacturer in decentralized and centralized supply chain when the supply chain reduces emissions or not under stochastic market demand. Thirdly, it investigates the optimal emission reduction level by mathematical modeling.
3. Basic Assumptions and Model Building
This paper considers a two-stage supply chain system consisting of one manufacturer
3.1. Basic Assumptions
Assumption 1.
In order to strengthen the emission reduction, it is assumed that the government will impose penalties on the manufacturer that does not reduce emissions. The fine is
Assumption 2.
It is assumed that the carbon emission of the manufacturer’s unit product is
Assumption 3.
It is assumed that the manufacturer’s emission reduction cost is
Assumption 4.
It is assumed that the consumer demand
Assumption 5.
It is assumed that the direct production cost is
In order to intuitively demonstrate the meaning of each parameter and variable in the above assumptions, we present the symbols and definitions of the parameters in Table 1.
Table 1
Parameters and variables.
Notation | Descriptions |
---|---|
|
Fine multiple of the wholesale price of the unit product., 0< |
t | Tax per unit of carbon emissions. |
|
The carbon emissions of the manufacturer’s unit product, it also represents the manufacturer’s production technology level. |
p | The purchase price that consumers are willing to pay, |
v | Constant. |
k | Consumer’s sensitivity to the carbon footprint. |
|
Carbon emission reduction level of the supply chain. |
|
Manufacturer’s emission reduction cost. |
|
Emission reduction cost coefficient |
h | Retailer’s order quantity |
|
Revenue sharing coefficient, that is, the ratio of the sales revenue of the retailer. |
|
The ratio of the sales revenue of the manufacturer. |
x | Consumer demand |
c | Direct production cost of the manufacturer’s yielding unit goods. |
|
Publicity expense of the unit product. |
|
Storage and transportation cost of the unit product. |
3.2. Model Construction
This paper first divides the supply chain into two types according to whether or not reducing emissions. Next, it further discusses the revenue model, wholesale price, order quantity of the supply chain from decentralized, and centralized decision-making.
3.2.1. Revenue Model with Non-Emission Reduction under Stochastic Demand in the Supply Chain
When the supply chain does not reduce emissions, the level of carbon emission reduction is
Proposition 6.
When the supply chain does not reduce emissions, the retailer’s revenue is a concave function of the order quantity, and there is a unique order quantity that maximizes the retailer’s revenue.
Proof.
The first-order partial derivative of (1) on order quantity
And the second-order partial derivative of Eq. (1) on
Because the retail price
When (3) equals zero, the order quantity
(1) Revenue of the Retailer and the Manufacturer in the Decentralized Supply Chain. Let
Proposition 7.
In the decentralized supply chain with no reducing emissions, the manufacturer’s revenue is a concave function of the wholesale price, and there is a unique wholesale price that can maximize the manufacturer’s revenue.
Proof.
It can be known from (2) that when the revenue sharing coefficient
The second-order partial derivative of
The first-order partial derivative of (5) on
Further, the second-order partial derivative of
Substitute (9) and (10) into (8), we can obtain
We rewrite the numerator of
Based on the previous assumptions, it illustrates the manufacturer’s profit
For the second part in (13), we firstly substitute
Hence, it can be deduced that the second part in (13) is greater than zero.
We further analyze the third part of (13). Since consumer demand distribution function
We further have
According to (5),
When (16) equals zero, the optimal wholesale price of the manufacturer in the decentralized supply chain is
After the manufacturer determines the optimal wholesale price, the retailer acts as the follower to match the optimal order quantity. At this time, the optimal expected revenue for the retailer and the manufacturer is
(2) Revenue of the Retailer and the Manufacturer in the Centralized Supply Chain. According to (1) and (2), the expected revenue of the supply chain as a whole is
The first-order partial derivative of (20) on
When (21) equals 0, the order quantity
And it can be deduced that the optimal wholesale price in the centralized supply chain without reducing emissions is
By substituting (23) into (5), we can obtain the optimal order quantity
For the centralized supply chain without reducing emissions, the optimal expected revenue of the retailer and the manufacturer is
It can be seen from (25) and (26) that the retailer’s revenue in the centralized supply chain increases with the rise of the revenue sharing coefficient
Hence, there exist
When the revenue sharing contract is reached, the retailer and the manufacturer can get more profits only if the value of
3.2.2. Revenue Model with Emission Reduction under Stochastic Demand in the Supply Chain
When the manufacturer reduces emissions, the expected consumers’ stochastic demand is expressed as
Let the first-order partial derivative of (28) on
Proposition 8.
When the supply chain reduces emission, the retailer’s revenue is a concave function of the order quantity, and there exists a unique order quantity that can maximize the retailer’s revenue; the manufacturer’s revenue function is a concave function of the wholesale price, and there exists a unique wholesale price that can maximize the manufacturer’s revenue.
The proof process of Proposition 8 is the same as Propositions 6 and 7. Moreover, we will analyze the revenue of the retailer and the manufacturer in the decentralized and centralized supply chain with emission reduction.
(1) Revenue of the Retailer and the Manufacturer in the Decentralized Supply Chain. In the decentralized supply chain, the revenue sharing coefficient
Let the above equation be zero, and we get the manufacturer’s optimal wholesale price
where
(2) Revenue of the Retailer and the Manufacturer in the Centralized Supply Chain. In the centralized supply chain, the revenue sharing coefficient
The first-order partial derivative of (35) on
When (36) equals 0, the optimal order quantity
By solving the above equation set, the optimal wholesale price for centralized supply chain with emission reduction can be obtained; that is,
Substituting (38) into (30), the optimal order quantity
For the centralized supply chain with emission reduction, the optimal expected revenue of the retailer and the manufacturer are as follows:
Using the same analysis method as Section 3.2.1 (2), this section considers that the benefits of the retailer and the manufacturer in the centralized supply chain cannot be less than the benefits obtained in the decentralized supply chain; hence, we have
4. Optimal Emission Reduction Level Based on Carbon Tax and Consumers’ Low-Carbon Preferences under Stochastic Demand
The final revenue of the supply chain is determined by sales revenue and production costs. On the one hand, sales revenue is determined by consumer demand and product price; with the consumers’ expected demand
4.1. Impact of Consumers’ Low-Carbon Preferences on Revenue in Supply Chain Emission Reduction
As shown in (28), the consumers’ low-carbon preferences in the supply chain reduction are reflected in the product retail price
Proposition 9.
In the case of emission reduction, the optimal revenue of members in the centralized supply chain is strictly monotonously decreasing with respect to consumers’ low-carbon preferences. In the decentralized supply chain, only when Condition (I) is satisfied can the retailer’s optimal revenue be strictly monotonously increasing of the consumers’ low-carbon preferences. Only when Condition (II) is met can the manufacturer’s optimal revenue strictly monotonously decrease with respect to consumers’ low-carbon preferences.
Condition (
Condition (
Proof.
For the centralized supply chain, the first-order partial derivative of (39) on
Substituting (45) into (40), we get the first-order partial derivative on k:
Similarly, it can be proved that
Since (46) and (47) are greater than zero, the manufacturer’s optimal revenue is strictly monotonously increasing with respect to consumers’ low-carbon preferences. Similarly, for decentralized supply chain, we have
When the parameters satisfy
When the parameters satisfy
4.2. Optimal Emission Reduction Level in the Supply Chain
Since the choice of emission reduction level in the supply chain will have an impact on the revenue of the retailer and the manufacturer, we study the optimal emission reduction level of the manufacturer as below.
Proposition 10.
When the supply chain reduces emission, the optimal revenue of the retailer in the centralized (or decentralized) supply chain is strictly monotonously increasing with respect to the emission reduction level.
Proof.
In the centralized supply chain, the optimal order quantity satisfies the following equation:
And the first-order partial derivative of (52) on
It can be seen that the optimal order quantity is strictly monotonously increasing with respect to the emission reduction level.
The first-order partial derivative of (40) on
Similarly, in the decentralized supply chain, it can be deduced that
When the parameters satisfy
Proposition 11.
When the supply chain reduces emissions, there exists a unique optimal emission reduction level in the centralized (or decentralized) supply chain that maximizes the manufacturer’s revenue.
Proof.
First, the second-order partial derivative of (52) on
Substituting (46) into (41), we get the second-order partial derivative of (41) on
In (58), since
In the centralized supply chain, when
And the manufacturer’s optimal revenue is
Similarly, in the decentralized supply chain, we have
When the parameters satisfy
5. Simulation Analysis
In this section, we present a simulation analysis to show how our analysis works under the stated assumptions. Firstly, this paper analyzes the relationship between consumers’ low-carbon preferences and the revenue of supply chain members. Then it discusses the impact of government’s punitive measures on the manufacturer’s emission reduction level and compares the decision process of centralized supply chain and decentralized supply chain with emission reduction. Furthermore, it studies the mechanism of emission reduction level on the revenue sharing coefficient in the centralized supply chain and finally explores the impact of carbon tax and consumers’ low-carbon preferences on the optimal emission reduction level in the centralized supply chain. Referring to the study by Du et al. [13], we solve the problem with the proposed model in which k=0.5,
5.1. Impact of Consumers’ Low-Carbon Preferences on the Revenue of Supply Chain Members
With the growing popularity of environmental consciousness, consumers are willing to pay more for low-carbon products. As can be seen from
In Figures 1–6, the horizontal axis represents the consumers’ low-carbon preferences, and the vertical axis represents the product retail price or supply chain members’ revenue. It can be seen that, in the decentralized supply chain, when other parameters are given, the product retail price and the optimal revenue of the manufacturer are all strictly monotonously decreasing with respect to consumers’ low-carbon preferences, while the optimal revenue of the retailer is strictly monotonously increasing on the consumers’ low-carbon preferences. In the centralized supply chain, the product retail price and the optimal revenue of members are strictly monotonously decreasing on the consumers’ low-carbon preferences. The relationships between the consumers’ low-carbon preferences and the revenue of supply chain members that reflected in Figures 1–6 are consistent with Proposition 9.
5.2. Analysis of the Impact of Government’s Punitive Measures on Manufacturer’s Emission Reduction Level
According to (1), (2), (28), and (29), we obtain the figures (Figures 7–10), which show the impact of wholesale price and emission reduction level on the revenue of the manufacturer and the retailer in the centralized and decentralized supply chain under the conditions of emission reduction and nonreduction, respectively. And we further analyze the impact of the government’s punitive measures on the emission reduction level of the manufacturer. In Figures 7–10, the x-axis represents the wholesale price
As can be seen from Figure 7, for a decentralized supply chain, the manufacturer’s revenue increases first and then decreases as the wholesale price increases. At the given level of emission reduction, there is always an optimal wholesale price that can maximize the manufacturer’s revenue. As the emission reduction level increases, the manufacturer’s revenue rises first and then decreases, but it is not as obvious as the case of the wholesale price changes. When the wholesale price is given, there is always an optimal emission reduction level that can maximize the manufacturer’s revenue. In the decentralized supply chain of Figure 8, the retailer’s revenue decreases as the wholesale price increases. When the manufacturer’s emission reduction level is getting larger, the retailer’s revenue is slowly increasing, but it does not show the significant characteristics like the manufacturer’s revenue changes with the emission reduction level. In Figure 7, the curve
As can be seen from Figures 9 and 10, in the centralized supply chain, the impact of emission reduction level and wholesale price on the revenue of supply chain members is basically the same as that of decentralized supply chain, and the manufacturer get more revenue from the retailer through a revenue sharing contract. We further find that if the government applies the punitive measures and the manufacturer does not reduce emissions, the revenue of the supply chain members will appear as a curve in the figure. Furthermore, the curves in Figures 7–10 are always below the surfaces because the government takes punitive measures against the manufacturer. When the manufacturer does not reduce emissions, the government will impose fines on the manufacturer, thus reducing the overall revenue of the retailer and the manufacturer. Therefore, when introducing a penalty mechanism, emission reduction is the optimal choice for the supply chain. Furthermore, the relationships among the wholesale price, emission reduction level, and the revenue of supply chain members shown in Figures 7–10 are consistent with Propositions 7, 8, 10, and 11.
5.3. Comparison of the Revenue of Supply Chain Members in the Decentralized and Centralized Supply Chain under Different Emission Reduction Level
The manufacturer proposes the emission reduction level and the optimal wholesale price, and the retailer accordingly selects the optimal order quantity. From (33), (34), (40), and (41), we can get the results of the optimal revenue of the retailer and the manufacturer with the changes of the emission reduction level in the centralized and decentralized supply chain. Let
In Figure 11, the horizontal axis represents the emission reduction level
5.4. Impact of Changes in Emission Reduction Level on the Revenue Sharing Coefficient under Centralized Supply Chain
In the centralized supply chain, the manufacturer and the retailer reach the revenue sharing contract. Only when the revenue sharing coefficient
Table 2
Effect of carbon tax and consumers’ low-carbon preferences on the reasonable range of the revenue sharing coefficient under different emission reduction level.
t=10 | ||||||
|
||||||
k=0.1 | k=0.5 | k=0.9 | ||||
|
||||||
Δe | a | b | a | b | a | b |
|
||||||
0 | 0.0413 | 0.8217 | 0.1019 | 0.6353 | 0.1708 | 0.4202 |
|
||||||
10 | 0.0412 | 0.8219 | 0.0994 | 0.6430 | 0.1618 | 0.4483 |
|
||||||
20 | 0.0411 | 0.8221 | 0.0970 | 0.6502 | 0.1539 | 0.4731 |
|
||||||
30 | 0.0410 | 0.8224 | 0.0948 | 0.6569 | 0.1468 | 0.4950 |
|
||||||
40 | 0.0410 | 0.8226 | 0.0927 | 0.6632 | 0.1404 | 0.5146 |
|
||||||
t=20 | ||||||
|
||||||
k=0.1 | k=0.5 | k=0.9 | ||||
|
||||||
Δe | a | b | a | b | a | b |
|
||||||
0 | 0.0415 | 0.8216 | 0.1029 | 0.6323 | 0.1730 | 0.4137 |
|
||||||
10 | 0.0414 | 0.8218 | 0.1003 | 0.6403 | 0.1637 | 0.4426 |
|
||||||
20 | 0.0413 | 0.8221 | 0.0979 | 0.6476 | 0.1555 | 0.4681 |
|
||||||
30 | 0.0412 | 0.8223 | 0.0956 | 0.6545 | 0.1483 | 0.4906 |
|
||||||
40 | 0.0411 | 0.8225 | 0.0935 | 0.6610 | 0.1418 | 0.5107 |
|
||||||
t=30 | ||||||
|
||||||
k=0.1 | k=0.5 | k=0.9 | ||||
|
||||||
Δe | a | b | a | b | a | b |
|
||||||
0 | 0.0416 | 0.8215 | 0.1040 | 0.6293 | 0.1752 | 0.4071 |
|
||||||
10 | 0.0415 | 0.8217 | 0.1013 | 0.6374 | 0.1656 | 0.4368 |
|
||||||
20 | 0.0414 | 0.8219 | 0.0988 | 0.6450 | 0.1572 | 0.4629 |
|
||||||
30 | 0.0413 | 0.8222 | 0.0965 | 0.6521 | 0.1498 | 0.4861 |
|
||||||
40 | 0.0413 | 0.8224 | 0.0943 | 0.6587 | 0.1431 | 0.5067 |
Note: - indicates that the data does not satisfy the condition and is null.
For every 10-unit increase in emission reduction level, when k=0.1, the lower limit of the revenue sharing coefficient will be expanded by about 0.2%, and the upper limit will be increased by about 0.0002; when k=0.5, the lower limit of
5.5. Impact of Carbon Tax and Consumers’ Low-Carbon Preferences on Optimal Emission Reduction Level in the Centralized Supply Chain
From the previous analysis, it is known that for supply chain members, emission reduction is better than no emission reduction, and the centralized supply chain is better than decentralized supply chain. Consumers’ low-carbon preferences and government-developed carbon tax policy, which we mainly focus on in this section, have important impacts on the emission reduction level. The relationships among carbon tax, consumers’ low-carbon preferences, and emission reduction level according to (40) are illustrated in Figures 12 and 13.
[figure omitted; refer to PDF] [figure omitted; refer to PDF]In Figure 12, the horizontal axis represents the emission reduction level, and the vertical axis denotes the revenue of the centralized supply chain with emission reduction. While the consumers’ low-carbon preferences are given, the three curves, respectively, indicate the overall revenue of the supply chain when the carbon tax t=10, 20, and 30. It can be seen that there is always a maximum point on each curve; hence, when the consumers’ low-carbon preferences are given, there exists an optimal emission reduction level that can maximize the overall revenue of the supply chain. In addition, as the carbon tax increases, the revenue curve changes from
In Figure 13, when the carbon tax is given, the three curves represent the change in the overall revenue of the supply chain with emission reduction level when k=0.1, 0.5, and 0.9. It can be seen that there exists a maximum point on each curve. Therefore, when the carbon tax is given, there is an optimal emission reduction level to maximize the overall revenue of the supply chain. Furthermore, as consumers’ low-carbon preferences increase, the curve changes from
6. Conclusion
This paper focuses on the emission reduction level of supply chain, taking into account consumers’ low-carbon preferences, stochastic market demand, and carbon tax policy. Firstly, it constructs a function of retail price on consumers’ low-carbon preferences and emission reduction level, which avoids the research flaws caused by the constant retail price, and accords with the fact that consumers with low-carbon preferences are willing to pay more for low-carbon products. Secondly, by introducing the penalty mechanism of emission reduction and using the reverse derivation method, this paper derives four revenue models of the retailer and the manufacturer in decentralized and centralized supply chain under stochastic market demand. Thirdly, it investigates the optimal emission reduction level of supply chain based on carbon tax and consumers’ low-carbon preferences under stochastic demand through mathematical modeling and also takes simulation analysis. The numerical results provide important organizational and policy insights on the following. (i) In the decentralized supply chain, the manufacturer’s (or the retailer’s) optimal revenue is strictly monotonously decreasing (or increasing) with respect to consumers’ low-carbon preferences. In the centralized supply chain, the optimal revenue of the retailer or manufacturer is strictly monotonously decreasing with respect to consumers’ low-carbon preferences. (ii) The retailer’s revenue is a concave function of the order quantity, and there exists a unique order quantity that maximizes the retailer’s revenue. The manufacturer’s revenue is a concave function of the wholesale price, and there exists a unique wholesale price that maximizes the manufacturer’s revenue. (iii) Under the influence of penalties, the manufacturer with emission reduction will bring excess benefits to supply chain members. Furthermore, the revenue sharing contract will increase the benefits of manufacturer and retailer in the centralized supply chain, which is better than the decentralized supply chain. (iv) When consumers’ low-carbon preferences are constant, there is an optimal emission reduction level that maximizes the overall revenue of the supply chain. As the carbon tax increases, the optimal emission reduction level gradually increases, which indicates that the government’s appropriate increase in carbon tax can stimulate the manufacturer to reduce emissions. (v) When the carbon tax is given, the optimal emission reduction level of the supply chain is improved as the consumer’s low-carbon preferences increases. (vi) With the increase of emission reduction level, the range of the revenue sharing coefficient becomes wider and wider, and it is easier for supply chain members to reach a revenue sharing contract. However, when consumers’ low-carbon preferences and carbon tax increase, the opposite is true.
Due to space limitations, there are still some deficiencies in this paper. Firstly, this study only considers the emission reduction under the secondary supply chain mechanism of the retailer and the manufacturer, but does not study the overall carbon emission reduction from the multilevel supply chain system composed of suppliers, manufacturers, retailers and consumers. Secondly, this study does not consider the dynamic game problem in the emission reduction of the retailer and the manufacturer, so it does not explore the evolutionary stabilization strategy of the members’ emission reduction input behavior. In addition, it only considers the consumers’ low-carbon preferences, but in practice, the channel preference of the consumer is also a key factor affecting market demand and price. Therefore, we believe that under the multilevel supply chain system, considering the multiple preferences of consumers and introducing dynamic game methods to deeply explore the emission reduction level of supply chain will become a new research field in the future.
Conflicts of Interest
The authors declare that there are no conflicts of interest regarding the publication of this paper.
Acknowledgments
This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China under Grant no. 71171155, Xi’an Social Sciences Planning Fund major projects under Grant no. 17J92, Special Scientific Research Project of Education Department of Shaanxi Province under Grant nos. 18JK0535 and 16JK1527, Xi’an Development and Reform Commission Regional Economic Issues under Grant no. SXTY2018-08-15, and Humanities and Social Sciences Research Planning Fund of Ministry of Education under Grant no. 19YJA630080.
[1] A. Nagurney, Z. Liu, T. Woolley, "Optimal endogenous carbon taxes for electric power supply chains with power plants," Mathematical and Computer Modelling, vol. 44 no. 9-10, pp. 899-916, DOI: 10.1016/j.mcm.2006.02.018, 2006.
[2] D. Gros, P. Lane, S. Langfield, "Too late, too sudden: Transition to a low-carbon economy and systemic risk," European Systemic Risk Board Report of the Advisory Scientific Committee, 2016.
[3] J. Xie, H. Dai, Y. Xie, L. Hong, "Effect of carbon tax on the industrial competitiveness of Chongqing, China," Energy for Sustainable Development, vol. 47, pp. 114-123, DOI: 10.1016/j.esd.2018.09.003, 2018.
[4] L. Ibanez, G. Grolleau, "Can ecolabeling schemes preserve the environment?," Environmental and Resource Economics, vol. 40 no. 2, pp. 233-249, DOI: 10.1007/s10640-007-9150-3, 2008.
[5] Q. Wang, D. Zhao, L. He, "Contracting emission reduction for supply chains considering market low-carbon preference," Journal of Cleaner Production, vol. 120 no. 1, pp. 72-84, DOI: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2015.11.049, 2016.
[6] D. B. Marron, E. J. Toder, "Tax policy issues in designing a carbon tax," American Economic Review, vol. 104 no. 104, pp. 563-568, DOI: 10.1257/aer.104.5.563, 2015.
[7] G. E. Metcalf, "Market-based policy options to control u.s. greenhouse gas emissions," Journal of Economic Perspectives (JEP), vol. 23 no. 2,DOI: 10.1257/jep.23.2.5, 2009.
[8] X. Chen, G. Hao, "Sustainable pricing and production policies for two competing firms with carbon emissions tax," International Journal of Production Research, vol. 53 no. 21,DOI: 10.1080/00207543.2014.932928, 2014.
[9] D. Xiang, C. Lawley, "The impact of British Columbia's carbon tax on residential natural gas consumption," Energy Economics, vol. 80, pp. 206-218, DOI: 10.1016/j.eneco.2018.12.004, 2019.
[10] S. Ding, M. Zhang, Y. Song, "Exploring China's carbon emissions peak for different carbon tax scenarios," Energy Policy, vol. 129, pp. 1245-1252, DOI: 10.1016/j.enpol.2019.03.037, 2019.
[11] Y. Liu, Y. Y. Lu, "The economic impact of different carbon tax revenue recycling schemes in China: a model-based scenario analysis," Applied Energy, vol. 141 no. 1, pp. 96-105, DOI: 10.1016/j.apenergy.2014.12.032, 2015.
[12] X. Zhao, J. Yao, C. Sun, W. Pan, "Impacts of carbon tax and tradable permits on wind power investment in China," Journal of Renewable Energy, vol. 135, pp. 1386-1399, DOI: 10.1016/j.renene.2018.09.068, 2019.
[13] S. Du, J. Zhu, H. Jiao, W. Ye, "Game-theoretical analysis for supply chain with consumer preference to low carbon," International Journal of Production Research, vol. 53 no. 12, pp. 3753-3768, DOI: 10.1080/00207543.2014.988888, 2015.
[14] Z. G. Tao, Z. Y. Guang, S. Hao, H. J. Song, D. G. Xin, "Multi-period closed-loop supply chain network equilibrium with carbon emission constraints," Resources, Conservation & Recycling, vol. 104, pp. 354-365, DOI: 10.1016/j.resconrec.2015.07.016, 2015.
[15] Z. Luo, X. Chen, X. Wang, "The role of co-opetition in low carbon manufacturing," European Journal of Operational Research, vol. 253 no. 2, pp. 392-403, DOI: 10.1016/j.ejor.2016.02.030, 2016.
[16] N. D. Rao, B. J. Van Ruijven, K. Riahi, V. Bosetti, "Improving poverty and inequality modelling in climate research," Nature Climate Change, vol. 7 no. 12, pp. 857-862, DOI: 10.1038/s41558-017-0004-x, 2017.
[17] K. Cao, X. Xu, Q. Wu, Q. Zhang, "Optimal production and carbon emission reduction level under cap-and-trade and low carbon subsidy policies," Journal of Cleaner Production, vol. 167, pp. 505-513, DOI: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.07.251, 2017.
[18] S. R. Madani, M. Rasti-Barzoki, "Sustainable supply chain management with pricing, greening and governmental tariffs determining strategies: a game-theoretic approach," Computers & Industrial Engineering, vol. 105, pp. 287-298, DOI: 10.1016/j.cie.2017.01.017, 2017.
[19] D. F. Drake, P. R. Kleindorfer, L. N. Van Wassenhove, "Technology choice and capacity portfolios under emissions regulation," Production Engineering Research and Development, vol. 25 no. 6, pp. 1006-1025, DOI: 10.1111/poms.12523, 2016.
[20] B. Fahimnia, J. Sarkis, A. Choudhary, A. Eshragh, "Tactical supply chain planning under a carbon tax policy scheme: a case study," International Journal of Production Economics, vol. 164, pp. 206-215, DOI: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2014.12.015, 2015.
[21] X. Chen, Z. Luo, X. Wang, "Impact of efficiency, investment, and competition on low carbon manufacturing," Journal of Cleaner Production, vol. 143, pp. 388-400, DOI: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2016.12.095, 2017.
[22] S. Benjaafar, Y. Li, M. Daskin, "Carbon footprint and the management of supply chains: insights from simple models," IEEE Transactions on Automation Science and Engineering, vol. 10 no. 1, pp. 99-116, DOI: 10.1109/TASE.2012.2203304, 2012.
[23] D. Ghosh, J. Shah, "Supply chain analysis under green sensitive consumer demand and cost sharing contract," International Journal of Production Economics, vol. 164, pp. 319-329, DOI: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2014.11.005, 2015.
[24] W. Yu, R. Han, "Coordinating a two-echelon supply chain under carbon tax," Sustainability, vol. 9 no. 12, 2017.
[25] S. Shewmake, A. Okrent, L. Thabrew, M. Vandenbergh, "Predicting consumer demand responses to carbon labels," Ecological Economics, vol. 119, pp. 168-180, DOI: 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2015.08.007, 2015.
[26] L. Xia, W. Hao, J. Qin, F. Ji, X. Yue, "Carbon emission reduction and promotion policies considering social preferences and consumers’ low-carbon awareness in the cap-and-trade system," Journal of Cleaner Production, vol. 195, pp. 1105-1124, DOI: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.05.255, 2018.
[27] Z. Liuabc, "Consumer environmental awareness and competition in two-stage supply chains," European Journal of Operational Research, vol. 218 no. 3, pp. 602-613, DOI: 10.1016/j.ejor.2011.11.027, 2012.
[28] C.-M. Shuai, L.-P. Ding, Y.-K. Zhang, Q. Guo, J. Shuai, "How consumers are willing to pay for low-carbon products? - results from a carbon-labeling scenario experiment in China," Journal of Cleaner Production, vol. 83 no. 83, pp. 366-373, DOI: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2014.07.008, 2014.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer
Copyright © 2019 Liang Wang et al. This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License (the “License”), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. Notwithstanding the ProQuest Terms and Conditions, you may use this content in accordance with the terms of the License. https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/
Abstract
This article focuses on the level of supply chain emission reduction, taking into account consumers’ low-carbon preferences, stochastic market demand, and carbon tax policy. By introducing the emission reduction penalty mechanism and adopting reverse derivation method, it derives the revenue model of the retailer and the manufacturer in decentralized and centralized supply chain when the supply chain reduces emissions or is not under stochastic market demand. The research results are as follows. (i) The optimal retailer’s revenue is strictly monotonous increasing with respect to the consumers’ low-carbon preferences in the decentralized supply chain. However, in the centralized supply chain, the optimal revenue of the retailer and the manufacturer are strictly monotonously decreasing of the consumers’ low-carbon preferences respectively. (ii) The retailer’s revenue is a concave function of the order quantity, and there exists a unique order quantity that can maximize retailer’s revenue. The manufacturer’s revenue is a concave function of the wholesale price, and there exists a unique wholesale price that can maximize manufacturer’s revenue. (iii) When consumers’ low-carbon preferences are given, there is an optimal emission reduction level that maximizes the overall revenue of the supply chain. Furthermore, as the carbon tax increases, the optimal emission reduction level gradually rises. (iv) As the level of emission reduction in the supply chain increases, the range of the revenue sharing coefficient becomes larger, and it is easier for supply chain members to reach a revenue sharing contract. However, when consumers’ low-carbon preferences and carbon tax increase, the opposite is true.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer