This work is licensed under http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ (the “License”). Notwithstanding the ProQuest Terms and Conditions, you may use this content in accordance with the terms of the License.
1. Introduction
Supply Chain Management (SCM) is concerned with efficient management of the financial, material, and information flows among supply chain (SC) members [1]. The researchers are developing SC coordination, integration, and collaboration subject modes with forward or reverse stream strategies between different economic institutions to improve the overall performance of SC. In a decentralized SC, upstream supplier and downstream chain member, as independent decision maker, make each decision focusing on its own profit. At the same time, as a member in the value chain, their decisions and behaviors are mutually influenced. The behavioral preferences are affecting the decision-making of each chain member. The behavioral preferences will lead to unperformed decision-making which will cause the traditional win-lose strategy and deviates from total SC profit maximization [2]. It is imperative that the decentralized SC members make decisions together in an effort to minimize overall total cost and maximize total profit by customer satisfaction [3]. To improve overall performance, the SC members may behave as a part of the unified system and coordinate with each other under joint strategical decisions. Thus “coordination” comes into focus [4]. The most commonly accepted definition of the coordination in the SCM literature is “the act of managing dependencies between chain members and the joint effort of members working together towards mutually defined goals” [5]. The coordination of a strategic SC can be achieved by the independent segment of coordination such as “information systems’ coordination,” “logistics processes’ coordination,” and “contractual coordination” (financial trade-off’s) [6]. Information sharing system coordination is necessary to support critical business decisions that may impact to price, quality, cost, availability, lead time, and profit share. Information flow is on both directions from the upstream chain members to the downstream chain consumers or conversely from downstream to the upstream. Information is available from a single source, often from the carrier, and information sharing mostly depends on contractual responsibility with other chain members [7]. Additionally, different products flow consists of different information priority such as quality conditions, product availability, service level, market price, and even actual market potential (for more details, see [8]). As an example, the eggs are classified by the United States Department of Agriculture based on their external appearance and quality condition information, mostly priority of information sharing under the retailer’s advantage. In the European Union, eggs are not based on their external appearance but on their used farming methods (conventional or organic, barn range, free-range) [9].
This study focuses on SC contractual coordination with Blockchain system-based proper lifecycle information sharing effort. Our model is based on the influence of product lifecycle information sharing effort and consumers’ price sensitivity. The Nash equilibrium solution of the SCs is obtained by reverse induction method. The decisions of Blockchain system investment between the different contracts are analysed and compared with the centralized SC optimal decision. Finally, the constraints of the member's choice of blockchain investment are given, and the influence of the Blockchain system cost coefficient and the price sensitivity coefficient on the decision-making behaviors and expected profits of the suppliers and retailers are simulated. This paper further enriches the theoretical achievements on the SC contractual coordination and Blockchain system investigation. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides the model establishment, assumptions, and nomenclature. Section 3 presents the various models’ analysis under the BS investment and we also propose the fifth case as a BS cost sharing with revenue-sharing model. Section 4 and 5 provides the numerical study, comparison, and simulation analysis of the five cases. In Section 6, conclusion and direction of future research are given.
2. Literature Review
Only very recently were there some other new approaches introduced to the SCM practice. The available studies introduced and developed the Blockchain-based systems in a SC where the Blockchain system (BS) is a new solution for data management among SC members. Blockchain technology has been initially applied to the SC information system coordination segments such as international payment [10], healthcare [11], electric energy supply [12], and education [13] and even in logistics process traceability systems coordination [14]. The new decentralized traceability system based on Internet of Things (IoT) and the Blockchain technology will support SC products visibility in the physical distribution phase via proper real-time information sharing under the safety status of products. Additionally, Blockchain technologies reduce the risk of information sharing and data systems and bring more security to the information flow among all SC members. The applications of IoT and Blockchain technologies are mainly focused on the consumer, industrial, and public sectors. Most of the recent interest has mainly focused on the consumer appliances. The industrial applications are promising to improve operational management outcomes in different fields of industries [15]. Utilization and development of Blockchain technology with IoT in back and forward information flows of a SC would effectively guarantee the trusted coordination, by gathering, transferring, and sharing the authentic data in planning, processing, distributing, and selling links [16]. As information sharing technology develops, the other coordination mechanisms such as contractual coordination of SC will be adopted accordantly. The activities transformed by the Blockchain system will lead to the costly efforts; total profit of SC will rise in the stochastic markets due to both higher sales volume and higher retail prices. At the same time, the benefits from these systematic examinations under contractual coordination remain unclear, as does sharing of its cost and profit among the SC members. None of the literature on SCM has discussed these interesting and trusted Blockchain technology benefits under contractual coordination theories until now.
3. Model Description, Assumptions, and Parameters
This section derives the model establishment and nomenclature. In this study, the terms of Blockchain system, blockchain technology, blockchain (BS), and information system have been used interchangeably to mean the proper lifecycle information sharing effort.
3.1. Model Description and Establishment
The study focuses on sharing contractual coordination with Blockchain system-based product proper lifecycle information sharing effort. The paper investigates a two-stage SC consisting of a supplier who sells the products to a retailer and the retailer who sells the supplier's products to consumers. Consumers are sensitive to the product price and product “Lifecycle Information Trustworthy” (LIT) and need to consider both the product price and the LIT level when buying products. To satisfy the consumers' demand with product LIT level, the retailer puts efforts by the adoption of new BT. In order to obtain the model demand function, we adopt the framework established by Ghosh and Shah’s [17] and Song and Gao [18]. To further expand the study, we make a distinct category of study, investigating them according to their LIT level under BS investment. We need to define the meaning of “Product Lifecycle,” “Lifecycle Information,” “Trustworthy,” and “Blockchain system” in this model.
(i)
“Product Lifecycle” demonstrates “the series of stages and functional activities through which a product passes from the point of origin to the point of consumption” and it is mainly based on time and the proper value-added chain members.
(ii)
“Lifecycle Information” describes the jointly collected data of product's specific information which interchanges between the series of stages and functional activities from the point of origin to the point of consumption.
(iii)
“Trustworthy” is used to indicate “the value of customer’s perspective in order to optimize customer utility.” From customers’ perspective, they are much worried about having product lifecycle information as proper as possible with products that may have an impact on health.
(iv)
In our study, the definition of “Blockchain system” defines as a new decentralized information sharing technology, which can store the product Lifecycle Information in the chain of blocks. Specific information of a product can be stored in a shared system for the all SC participants including customers.
3.2. Assumptions and Nomenclature
We assume that the SC members can influence the market demand by exerting the Blockchain system-based product proper lifecycle information sharing effort. To address this issue, we consider a SC model consisting of an upstream supplier and a downstream retailer. The model in this paper is based on the following assumptions.
Hypothesis 1.
The supplier provides a product to the retailer at wholesale price and the retailer sells product to consumer at retail price. We assume that consumers are different in the valuation of the product’s proper lifecycle information trustworthy. We denote the “Lifecycle Information Trustworthy” level (alternatively called “LIT”), and for analytic simplicity we assume in the range of
Hypothesis 2.
The cost of the BS invested takes the form of
Hypothesis 3.
Total demand during the season is stochastic and sensitive to the product price and product LIT. Consumer’s sensitivity forces to consider both the product price and the product LIT level. Consumers preference is to get informed about product proper lifecycle, and when the LIT level of a product is higher, and the product price is lower, the product sales are greater. The actual market place demand
Hypothesis 4.
Consumer products can replace each other in the market with and without Blockchain system-based lifecycle information.
Hypothesis 5.
The retailer is the leader and the supplier is the follower.
We make the following parameters and meanings (Table 1):
Table 1
Nomenclature.
Parameters | Meaning |
|
Total market potential |
|
Product cost |
|
Sensitivity to product price |
|
Product retail price |
|
Product wholesale price |
|
Product LIT level under BS |
|
Sensitivity to the LIT level |
|
Cost sharing fraction |
|
RS fraction via bargaining |
|
Revenue-sharing fraction |
|
Total profit |
|
Optimal value |
|
Supplier’s profit |
|
Retailer’s profit |
|
Total SC’s profit |
|
Centralized SC with BS |
|
SL retailer own BS invest |
|
SL retailer’s BS cost sharing |
|
BS via bargaining RS |
|
BS invest with cost and RS |
4. The Models
In this section, the following scenarios are presented under the Stackelberg leader (SL) and Stackelberg follower (SF) power structures. For the comparison, we first examined a benchmark centralized SC model, which is known as the vertical integration model. The second is a decentralized SC scenario, where the retailer is a SL with passive SF supplier structural observation. The third scenario is the decentralized decision mode with Blockchain system cost sharing when the retailer is a SL and the supplier is a SF, similar to [17]. Through the fourth scenario, we examined RS via bargaining model, similar to [18]. The fifth scenario presents the Blockchain system-based strategical approach via cost sharing as well as with revenue sharing among the SC members under the SL retailer structure.
4.1. Case 1: Centralized SC Mode with Blockchain System (A Benchmark)
In the centralized SC scenario, where the sales margin
Taking the first and second partial derivatives of equation (2)with respect to
Substituting the optimal
4.2. Case 2: BS Based Information Sharing Effort under the Retailer Stackelberg Leadership
In the decentralized SC scenario, the supplier and retailer are making their decisions interdependently. In this decentralized decision-making structure, the retailer as a SL and the supplier as a passive SF mode is examined. Because of asymmetry information, the market demand trustworthy (satisfaction) level is available for the downstream retailer and it is simply based on customers’ experience of retention. The retailer as a SL exerts the Blockchain system-based product proper lifecycle information sharing effort and sets the selling price to maximize own profit. Accordingly, the supplier as a SF sets wholesale price. At this point, the profit functions of the SF supplier and SL retailer in the decentralized SC scenario with BS investment are given by
The total profit function of the whole decentralized SC with BS investment in any case is
First, we solve the profit function for the SF supplier. In this case, the SL retailer’s sales margin is
Next, we solve the profit function for the supplier from equation (8) by obtaining the first and second partial derivatives with respect to
We are putting the optimal values of
Finally, we are substituting all the optimal values into equations (7)–(9) and getting the maximum profits for the supplier
Table 2
Optimal values under the different SC decision-making.
|
Case 1 | Case 2 | Case 3 | Case 4 | Case 5 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
— |
|
|
|
|
|
— |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
4.3. Case 3: BS Based Effort Cost Sharing under the Retailer Stackelberg Leader Mode
In the decentralized SC scenarios, the supplier’s and retailer’s total profit are less than the centralized SC and the BS based product lifecycle information sharing effort is lower. Therefore, to achieve the optimal product proper lifecycle information sharing in a decentralized SC, the SL must invest a higher BS investment. However, the game follower may not be motivated to invest for the BS based information sharing. To address this case issue, the cost sharing contractual coordination is presented to the decentralized SC with BS, similar to [17]. The retailer as a SL invests a higher BS investment with two main parameters: retailer’s paid wholesale price
First, we solve the profit function for the retailer where the retailer’s sales margin is
Next, we solve the profit function for the supplier from equation (13) by obtaining the first and second partial derivatives with respect to
In this case, the supplier has significant motivation to participate in LIT sharing effort investment because portion of cost will be shared by the retailer. Let the optimal LIT level be the same as in the centralized SC:
Finally, we are substituting all the optimal values; we get
4.4. Case 4: Retailer’s BS Investment under the Revenue-Sharing Contract via Bargaining
In the decentralized SC scenarios, the supplier’s and retailer’s total profit are less than the centralized SC and the BS based lifecycle information sharing effort is lower. Therefore, to achieve the optimal product lifecycle information sharing in a decentralized SC, the SL must invest a higher BS investment. However, the game follower may not be motivated to invest for the BS-based information sharing. To address this case issue, the cost-sharing contractual coordination is presented to the decentralized SC with BS, similar to [18].
When the retailer as a SL invests a higher BS investment, the bargaining RS contract includes two parameters: retailer’s paid wholesale price
First, we solve the profit function for the retailer where the retailer’s sales margin is
Next, we solve the profit function for the supplier from equation (18) by obtaining the first and second partial derivatives with respect to
We are putting the optimal values into equation (20); therefore, our optimal retailor price is
To get the value of
Finally, we substitute the value of
4.5. Case 5: BS Cost and Revenue-Sharing Model under Retailer Stackelberg Leadership
In this case, a decentralized SC scenario under the retailer SL structure presents the Blockchain system investment via cost sharing as well as with revenue-sharing model.
We assume that the leader maximizes the profit of the whole SC as an effort added coordinator, and we use revenue-sharing contract to coordinate the retailer’s and supplier’s decision-making. In other words, the supplier is committed to providing the retailer a lower wholesale price
The total profit function of the whole SC with BS cost is
First, we solve the profit function for the retailer where the retailer’s sales margin is
Next, we solve the profit function for the supplier from equation (24) by obtaining the first and second partial derivatives with respect to
We are putting the optimal values into equation (27); therefore, our optimal retailor price is
Finally, we are substituting all the optimal values into equations (9), (24), and (25) and getting the maximum profits for the supplier, retailer, and the whole SC under case 5. Specific values are listed in Table 2.
5. Comparison and Simulation Analysis
In order to obtain valuable conclusions and efficiency of the models, we use MATLAB software in this section. We explore the effects of different parameters on the decision-making behaviors and profits of SC members with the numerical values. We assume that the consumers sensitivity to price
Table 3
Parameters and values.
Parameter |
|
|
|
|
|
Value | 8 | 100 | 5 | 0.5 | 0.5 |
5.1. Comparison
We compare the cost coefficient of lifecycle information sharing effort, the consumer’s price sensitivity coefficient, and expected profits of the suppliers and the retailers. The values of the parameters and the results under the five cases are summarized in Table 2.
Based on the above five models’ optimal decision variables and total profits comparison, we can derive the following propositions.
Proposition 1.
The LIT level of a product is on the highest level under the centralized SC’s effort added case and on the lowest level under the bargaining RS model and the decentralized SC SL effort added case model. The LIT level of the product under the cost and revenue-sharing contract is higher than that under the decentralized SC case, SL retailer cost-sharing case, and the bargaining revenue-sharing case. Under the cost and revenue-sharing contract if consumers’ sensitivity to the price is greater, the coordinate of SC will be difficult. However, if consumers’ sensitivity to the LIT is greater, the SC with BS investment will be easy to coordinate
Proof of Proposition 1.
Proposition 2.
When the cost-sharing coefficient
Proof of Proposition 2.
The total profit under the BS investment cost and revenue-sharing contract is
Then, we compare the SC profit under cost and revenue-sharing contract with other cases in the decentralized SC and benchmark SC; we got
5.2. Simulation Analysis
We simulate the consumer’s price sensitivity coefficient
[figures omitted; refer to PDF]
[figure omitted; refer to PDF]
[figures omitted; refer to PDF]
[figures omitted; refer to PDF]
To see both sensitivity performances in our model, we illustrate the model under the effects of consumers’ sensitivity
6. Conclusions and Future Research
This paper examined two-stage SC consisting of a supplier and a retailer where the retailer is the leader. The following five scenarios were examined: a benchmark model where there is a single decision-maker; a decentralized model via retailer invested lifecycle information sharing effort; a cost-sharing model under retailer SL; a bargaining RS model under retailer SL; the cost and revenue-sharing model under retailer SL. The paper constructs a SC model based on product proper lifecycle information sharing effort cost coefficient, consumer’s price sensitivity coefficient with the decision-making behaviors, and expected profits of SC members. With the help of game theory, the Nash equilibrium solution of the SC under different circumstances is obtained. Total SC profit of the five models is solved by reverse induction method, and the results are compared and analysed. Our study is providing incentives to the upstream SC by proper sharing of its cost and revenue simultaneously. In addition, cost and revenue-sharing coordination mechanism will give sustainability to building long-term relationships between the members of decentralized SC. Our future research will focus on investigation of the models in different industries with uncertain demand to understand the impact of the product and process information sharing via BS. Future research could focus on the global distribution of demand to minimize the risk among multiple competing members.
Acknowledgments
This study was supported by the National Social Science Foundation of China (no. 18BGL104). The authors are grateful to the nonprofit institution “China Scholarship Council” and “Southwest Jiaotong University National United Engineering Laboratory of Integrated and Intelligent Transportation” for providing support for this research.
[1] R., Y. B. Anupindi, "Supply contracts with quantity commitments and stochastic demand," Quantitative Models for Supply Chain Management, Handbooks in Operations Research and Management Science, 1999.
[2] M. Jian, Y. L. Wang, "Decision-making strategies in supply chain management with a waste-averse and stockout-averse manufacturer," Advances in Production Engineering & Management, vol. 13 no. 3, pp. 345-357, DOI: 10.14743/apem2018.3.295, 2018.
[3] R. B. Handfield, E. L. J. Nichols, Introduction to Supply Chain Management, 1999.
[4] K. Arshinder, A. Kanda, S. G. Deshmukh, "A review on supply chain coordination: coordination mechanisms, managing uncertainty and research directions," Supply Chain Coordination Under Uncertainty, International Handbooks On Information Systems, pp. 39-82, 2011.
[5] T. W. Malone, K. Crowston, "The interdisciplinary study of coordination," ACM Computing Surveys, vol. 26 no. 1, pp. 87-119, DOI: 10.1145/174666.174668, 1994.
[6] R. M. H. J. B. Rice, Network Master & Three Dimensions of Supply Network Coordination: An Introductory Essay, 2002.
[7] H. Wu, Z. Li, B. King, Z. Ben Miled, J. Wassick, J. Tazelaar, "A distributed ledger for supply chain physical distribution visibility," Information, vol. 8 no. 4,DOI: 10.3390/info8040137, 2017.
[8] H. L. Lee and S. Whang, Research Paper Series Graduate School of Business Information Sharing in a Supply Chain, no. 1549
[9] The Eggs Classification, Statista, 2017, https://www.statista.com/statistics/273951/
[10] P.-W. Chen, B.-S. Jiang, C.-H. Wang, "Blockchain-based payment collection supervision system using pervasive Bitcoin digital wallet," Proceedings of the International Conference on Wireless and Mobile Computing, Networking and Communications,DOI: 10.1109/wimob.2017.8115844, .
[11] T. Bocek, B. B. Rodrigues, T. Strasser, B. Stiller, "Blockchains everywhere - a use-case of blockchains in the pharma supply-chain," Proceedings of the IM 2017—2017 IFIP/IEEE International Symposium on Integrated Network and Service Management, pp. 772-777, DOI: 10.23919/inm.2017.7987376, .
[12] F. Knirsch, A. Unterweger, D. Engel, "Privacy-preserving blockchain-based electric vehicle charging with dynamic tariff decisions," Computer Science-Research and Development, vol. 33 no. 1-2, pp. 71-79, DOI: 10.1007/s00450-017-0348-5, 2018.
[13] A. Grech, A. F. Camilleri, Blockchain in Education, 2017.
[14] W. Meng, E. W. Tischhauser, Q. Wang, Y. Wang, J. Han, "When intrusion detection meets blockchain technology: a review," IEEE Access, vol. 6, pp. 10179-10188, DOI: 10.1109/access.2018.2799854, 2018.
[15] S. Rhee, "Catalyzing the internet of things and smart Cities : global city teams challenge," .
[16] F. Tian, "An agri-food supply chain traceability system for China based on RFID & blockchain technology," Proceedings of the 2016 13th International Conference on Service Systems and Service Management, ICSSSM 2016, .
[17] D. Ghosh, J. Shah, "Supply chain analysis under green sensitive consumer demand and cost sharing contract," International Journal of Production Economics, vol. 164, pp. 319-329, DOI: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2014.11.005, 2015.
[18] H. Song, X. Gao, "Green supply chain game model and analysis under revenue-sharing contract," Journal of Cleaner Production, vol. 170, pp. 183-192, DOI: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.09.138, 2018.
[19] Q. Zheng, P. Ieromonachou, T. Fan, L. Zhou, "Supply chain contracting coordination for fresh products with fresh-keeping effort," Industrial Management & Data Systems, vol. 117 no. 3, pp. 538-559, DOI: 10.1108/imds-04-2016-0139, 2017.
[20] G. P. Cachon, M. A. Lariviere, "Capacity choice and allocation: strategic behavior and supply chain performance," Management Science, vol. 45 no. 8, pp. 1091-1108, DOI: 10.1287/mnsc.45.8.1091, 1999.
[21] W. K. Chiang, D. Chhajed, J. D. Hess, "Direct marketing, indirect profits : a strategic analysis of dual-channel supply-chain design," Management Science, vol. 49 no. 1,DOI: 10.1287/mnsc.49.1.1.12749, 2003.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer
Copyright © 2020 Saidjahon Hayrutdinov et al. This work is licensed under http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ (the “License”). Notwithstanding the ProQuest Terms and Conditions, you may use this content in accordance with the terms of the License.
Abstract
The study proposes a supply chain contractual coordination model based on the product lifecycle information sharing effort and consumers' price sensitivity to a product with the Blockchain system. This paper examined the following five scenarios: (1) centralized supply chain with Blockchain system-based product lifecycle information sharing investment; (2) Stackelberg leader retailer processed and invested Blockchain system scenario; (3) retailer processed the Blockchain system cost-sharing scenario; (4) retailer processed Blockchain system investment through bargaining the revenue-sharing model; (5) Blockchain system investment under the cost and revenue-sharing contract. The study used the game theory reverse induction method to compare the Nash equilibrium solutions under different decision-making scenarios and discussed the chain member’s constraint condition of Blockchain system investment. We simulated and analysed the products’ lifecycle information sharing effort cost factor, the influence of price sensitivity coefficient, and expected profits of the supplier and retailer. The study results show that the product lifecycle information sharing effort under the Blockchain system increases the profit of the whole chain and decreases with the increase of customer’s price sensitivity coefficient.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer