Abstract
The subject of this paper is a critique of the quasi-neoliberal violence of alternative institutions, which are the most problematic and most threatening brake phenomenon of transition. They have been produced, strengthened and reproduced by the authorities of most post-socialist countries in the last three decades. The aim of this paper is to demystify neoliberalism, its ideological, philosophical, and monistic absolutizations, as well as quasi-neoliberal manifestations, which in many post-socialist countries were carried out directly under the auspices of alternative institutions. Also, the goal is to shed light on the causes of the long-term crisis, chaos, institutional violence, and lawlessness, and to enable the recognition of too visible (albeit blurred), rhetorical and "messianic" recipes, which are, in fact, developmental shackles. The paper is based on two hypotheses: first, that alternative institutions have abused and enslaved formal and informal institutions in most transition countries, which has led to numerous economic and social problems, including threats to the rule of law, freedoms, and civilizational development, and second, that a transitional hindering mechanism was created, which generated a neoexploitative, apologetic, neo-totalitarian and crisis environment. The paper uses common methods of social and economic sciences, including the methods of generalization, description, abstraction, comparison, induction and deduction. In conclusion, it is stated that the phenomenological identification and critical demystification of the interest connections and conditioning of neoliberalism, alternative institutions, and the crisis have been carried out, and that their exponents (alleged reformers and new elites) had an extremely negative impact on social, economic, scientific, educational, cultural and institutional development, because they degraded and destroyed them.
Keywords: Neoliberalism, quasi-neoliberal violence, alternative institutions, transition countries, transitional crisis.
JEL Classification: O17, P37
Introduction
Neoliberalism as an ideology (and especially quasi-neoliberalism as its abuse) has many negative and dark sides, which its proponents have never pointed out or commented on. On the contrary, they knowingly (but clumsily) hid them. That is why we have tried in many works to prove that mysticism and simulacrum have no place in economics, and other social sciences, because civil behavior, rational choice, and competition are the essence of optimizing the social life. However, they have been distorted, reduced, blurred, and determined by a privileged minority, which has been politically, lobbyistically, and interestingly organized in most transition countries, subjected to social traumas. For three decades, this minority (the so-called new elites) has been directing, controlling, and exploiting the disorganized majority (broad masses of the people) in accordance with their networked interests, preferences, and goals.
If we view the the multiple crises in most post-socialist countries through the prism of basic causes (sophisticated forms of dictatorship, dogmatization, absolutization, ideologization, quasi-institutionalization (Draskovic, et al., 2019), neo-totalitarianization, and neoimperialization), it can be seen that all these processes were mainly based on monistic and privileged uncontrolled by people centers of power. In such a context, economic freedoms, competition, private property, and entrepreneurship (Panikarova, et al., 2000) as a desirable democratic phenomenon, remained just a slogan and a promise. They have been replaced by new and sophisticated forms of institutional and other violence.
The iterative reproduction of the multiple crises, including the transitional one, cannot be explained without critical light shed on alternative institutions as its main cause and instrument of governance and enrichment. For, they (as a specific form of informal and illegal rules of conduct) essentially denied and subordinated all formal and informal institutions to their influence. In this way, they directly weakened, denied, and/or relativized the corrective role of state regulatory institution. This is contrary not only to the logic of common sense regarding the possibility of implementing a consistent strategy of social and economic development, but also to the practice of developed countries. Due to all this, the paper attempts to explain:
* relations of connection and interdependence between neoliberalism, alternative institutions, and the transitional crisis,
* fact that neoliberalism in its pseudo form of manifestation has immorally legitimized egoism, i.e. individualism of narrow and privileged strata of society, and
* phenomenology of alternative institutions.
1.Neoliberal ideology
The practice of post-socialist countries which have implemented neoliberal ideology, philosophy, culture and the alleged messianic recipe for development, has immorally legitimized egoism, individualism of privileged and alternative institutions, instead of legitimizing widely propagated individualism and freedom on a mass scale. On the other hand, it has ignored goodwill, sacrifice, commitment, solidarity, and many civilizational values, and rejected every form of collectivism, even the most positive and socially necessary forms. Privileged interests have been turned into the sole guide and motive for economic and every other behavior. This has turned society into a managerial organization in which all social values have been marginalized and adapted to the greedy culture of business (Horvathova and Mokrisova, 2020), that has produced new risks and vulnerabilities (Kravchenko, 2018).
What has long been called neoliberalism in literature and rhetoric was actually a cover for the plunder of the people (middle and lower classes) by the top authorities (as the leaders of the alleged new elites and big capital). Neoliberalism has proved to be very strong and resilient in the United States, Great Britain, and the EU. It was based on the economic dominance of financial capital, the instruments of globalization, the phrases and apologetics of some theorists, and the control of economy and society by the leading parties. Accordingly, the neoliberals were ideological employees of financial and corporate capital (Tomas, 2000).
In most transition countries, however, the seductiveness of neoliberalism was much greater in terms of ideological symbolism, rhetoric, and false promises, than in the real and chaotic life (results) of post-socialist civilization. Under the slogan of neoliberalism, a quasineoliberal project has been realized secretly or openly, with all its vices, which spread everywhere like weeds, not even bringing the illusion of happiness and welfare, but only negative phenomenology, which openly and repeatedly threatens to destroy many achievements of previous civilizations in most post-socialist countries (Draskovic, 2020).
Neoliberalism was and remains an ideological attempt to impose a universal and submissive concept of power, which Western elites exported to many post-socialist and other underdeveloped countries. They presented it as the only (non-alternative) solution to all social and economic problems. But in fact, it was only a temporary and palliative solution to the accumulated problems of global elites, who have been buying foreign resources cheaply for years. At the same time, it was the main problem of the vast majority of the world's population and an effective instrument for realizing the interests of the political, corporate, and financial elite of the Western world.
For reminders, neoliberalism has advocated that the Washington Consensus recommendations should be seen as the ultimate (absolute) truth. Neoliberal ideology has been presented as a supposedly scientifically based, socially, economically, politically, geopolitically and geoeconomically useful philosophy - as the end of history. However, its basis was neither theoretical, nor consistent. It was an attempt of interest parties (organizations and individuals) to present this interest-driven and highly unjust ideology as sustainable and infallible.
There is no official state ideology in Western countries. But that does not mean that there is no quasi-state, a dominant ideology. This was and remains the illusion produced by many neoliberals. In the West (as a general term, and not specifically in each country) still dominates neoliberal ideology, which is persistently and sophisticatedly imposed on the rest of the world. Unlike culture as the most general social milieu, which essentially consists of many subcultures, different teachings and trends (multi-culturalism, which has no authoritarian inner core), each ideology strives for the privileged status of addressed social domination. Because of this, the attempt to impose neoliberal ideology as a neoliberal culture to the world is a great deception. A feature of every ideology is the desire of its bearers to spread concepts beyond the boundaries of the system ruled by that ideology.
The neoliberal aspiration to impose its value system as universal, which should be dominated by an unjust relationship between the center and the periphery (in the general sense), is a monistic-totalitarian and highly interest-driven project of the ruling elites (big capital). This project cynically implies the existence of (Draskovic, 2020):
* freedom for privileged elites, as opposed to mass freedoms for the vast majority (peoples and states),
* exploitation of subordinates,
* capital concentrations,
* various forms of monopoly,
* large differences in development and wealth,
* direct and indirect privileges,
* free institutional channels for capital expansion,
* abuse of the state regulatory institutions,
* rule of law deficit,
* strong alternative institutions,
* domination of financial neocolonialism,
* constant growth of external indebtedness,
* degradation of human freedoms and rights,
* ignoring the common good and social interest, and
* one global center of power.
All of the aforesaid drastically deforms not only culture (as a general social capsule and, conditionally, a synonym for informal institutions) (Alesina and Guliano, 2015), but also all value criteria, preferences, needs, and motivation, thus producing "normal anomie" (Kravchenko, 2014, pp. 3-10).
2.Destructivity of neoliberal philosophy and phenomenology
If countries and societies with implemented neoliberalism want to develop in the future, they must eliminate neoliberalism, not only in practice, but also in its intellectual basis. In other words, neoliberalism must be liquidated from the realm of the real and from the realm of the possible. For, the philosophy of neoliberalism enables and justifies a broad corpus of socio-economic destructions. It indoctrinates and cripples all segments of society, producing dehumanization and increasing effects of "normal traumas" (Kravchenko, 2020, pp. 150-159).
In order to prevent the spread of destructiveness, generated by neoliberalism, it is necessary to abandon this wrong and malicious concept, which proclaims the enormous damage it has proclaimed as good deeds! In order to get rid of neoliberal or quasi-neoliberal phrase called minimal state (or mockingly: market state - a term by D. Stojanov, 2013, p. 295) and the consequent modern anti-civilization shackles, people must understand the vicious role of intoxicating privileged interests, which are contained in the foundations of neoliberal philosophy.
The difference between small and large nations, underdeveloped and developed countries, post-socialist (institutionally hybrid) and Western (civil) societies is, among other things, in a very noticeable, widespread, and negative phenomenon. Namely, the former glorify, advocate, and respect the opinions of unruly alibi-economists and classic interest-driven party switchers, who have transformed from one monism to another, from socialist planners through neoliberal ideologues to alleged returnees to institutional frameworks. In latter, they are (very rare) simply marginalized.
Hayek's idea that neoliberalism (embodied in the free market) is the main weapon against the elements of neototalitarianism has been turned by false (alibi) reformers through alternative institutions into the ideology of neototalitarianism! In that sense, they used not only this new invention (alternative institutions) for controlling political, economic and social processes, but also the latest information and communication technologies, the socalled tools of soft power, smart power strategies, methods of organizing pink and velvet revolutions, information, network and hybrid wars.
The entire civilized, developed and democratic world is fighting resolutely and consistently against privileges with all its might. The existence of alternative institutions and other forms of institutional monism is inconceivable there (Popovic, et al., 2020). Due to this fact, normal people must ask themselves: why exemplary models of developed countries were not an inspiration in most post-socialist countries, but quasi-institutional, quasineoliberal, non-market, and illegal enrichment at any cost, which led to the functioning of the economy and society under the limited access to resources regime (North, et al., 2009)?!
The neoliberal story on structural reforms (without real institutional reforms) has always been and continues to be - illusion, fiction, absurdity, mere mask and farce. For, everywhere politics dominates over the economy. This is not only a problem of economics, but also of history, psychology, philosophy, sociology, and culture, without which economics cannot be understood and functions successfully.
In the three-decade period of transition, alternative institutions were active. They were closely linked to neoliberal recipes. This negative synergistic connection has constantly deepened the destructive economic, social, legal, ethical, and cultural phenomena, which have turned into a negative trend of breaking without building, and have significantly contributed to the overall crisis environment of transition. The mosaic of this general crisis picture was completed by the following problems:
* lack of political consensus with very pronounced internal political, religious, identity, and other divisions, as well as intensified political struggle for power,
* collectivist mentality of the people in relation to the government,
* manifestation of some anachronistic behaviors characteristic of patriarchal and paternalistic society,
* emphasized rhetoric of false promises,
* conglomerate inconsistency (organizational, institutional, and normative vacuum),
* mutant recombined order, which contains many anachronistic structures of the old system, and outdated rigid elements of the capitalist system,
* strategically meaningless, inconsistent, and palliative reforms,
* pronounced negative (usually party) selection of staff,
* expensive, interest-driven, and unsuccessful improvisations of economic reformers,
* replacing the former ideals with vices,
* ignoring successful role models and competition at all levels and in all areas,
* interference of state-political bodies in making economic decisions, etc.
These problems have been accompanied by a personality cult, the development of autocracy, concentration of power and economic power, long-term unchangeable government, populist rhetoric and arrogance, unjust and irrational growth of party intellectuals, nepotism, demagogic promises, imitation of democratic standards, mass apathy, controversial conditioning of employment by party membership, spreading the paradoxical superiority of superiors and subordinates, endangering human existence and dignity, degrading the educational system, hampering the development of the knowledgebased economy, etc.
Figure no. 1 shows new shackles (postsocialist) from the aspect of generating areas (origin).
We hypothesized that there are four basic areas that have predominantly influenced the generation of so-called new shackles: international community, culture, institutions and knowledge. In that sense, only the neo-imperialists shackles were generated in all of the mentioned areas. In three areas (culture, institutions and knowledge), five types of shackles were generated: neo-totalitarian, ideological and political, apologetic, quasi-neoliberal and alternative institutions. Finally, in two areas (institutions and knowledge), four types of shackles were generated: non-market, system, monistic and anti-development.
Starting from the criteria of the so-called systemic paradigms (Kornai, 2002), all analyzes of practice in most transition countries clearly show that this is a quasi-neoliberal concept of interest, as a new, disastrous and dogmatic experiment. Through the formation and strengthening of alternative institutions, it contributed to the emergence of new shackles, i.e. great abuses, turmoil, and anti-development issues problems in many transition countries. Therefore, this paper indicates the need to reconsider and eliminate the aforementioned socially unjust order.
3.Alternative institutions
The challenge of transitional (reform) changes in post-socialist countries appeared long ago, at a time when they were burdened by the ballast of the past and the uncertainty of the future. Most of them have not yet found a rational and effective response to that challenge. We believe that the main cause is insufficient and unsuccessful institutional change, i.e. the act of alternative institutions. There are very few articles in the economic literature which directly determine the existence and/or analyze the functioning of alternative institutions. This is understandable for Western authors, due to the absence or negligible importance of alternative institutions in developed countries. But, the authors from transition countries unjustifiably neglect the existence, functioning and great social and economic impact of alternative institutions.
They are always associated with quasi-institutional actions (from the shadow, criminal, opportunistic), therefore, they are not easy to investigate and explain. However, there are institutional and other indicators, which directly or indirectly indicate existence and negative impact of alternative institutions. These include the rule of law index, economic freedoms, innovation capacity, perceptions of corruption, global competitiveness, degree of inequality, non-market redistribution of resources, etc.
Although alternative institutions are not a direct subject of research in developed countries, nevertheless, traces related to them can be found in Western literature, such as:
* "exploitative approach to the state" within the so-called "interest approach" (North, 1981, p. 22) and the theory of social (public) choice (Buchanan, 1990),
* "rent-oriented motivation theory" (Krueger, 1974; Posner, 1975; Buchanan, et al., 1980; Tullock, 1996; Rose-Ackerman, 1999; Acemoglu and Verdier, 2000; Congleton and Hillman, 2015),
* theory of externalities (Buchanan and Tullock, 1997),
* theory of "predatory states" (Evans, 1993; Robinson, 1999; Przeworski and Limongi, 1993; Marcouiller and Young, 1995),
* theory of "total institutions" (Goffman, 1968, p. 41),
* theory of the influence of powerful administrative-bureaucratic groups (Mc Auley, 1991, p. 26),
* theory of "violence" ("system with limited access to resources") (North, et al., 2009),
* theory of opportunistic behavior and limited rationality (Williamson, 1985; 1985a) and
* theory of the so-called "rational bandits", who rule the so-called predatory state, creating the majority of the population deprived (alienated) of property (Olson, 2010).
The existence of alternative institutions is a characteristic of underdeveloped countries. This has been proved by many socio-pathological phenomena (corruption, non-market and legal enrichment, interest-lobbying log-rolling, monopolies, and various forms of market restrictions (Draskovic, et al., 2020). The reasons for this are numerous, from dependence on path dependency (work habits, mentality, achieved level of industrial development, way of regulating economy, level of investment in science, democratic achievements and traditions, economic, market and other freedoms, party monopoly, deficit of economic, legal, and other institutions, inherited cult of leader, effects of cultural factors (mentality, education and social consent) and the effects of social capital), through foreign economic and political influences (war environment, integrations, globalization, geopolitics, and geoeconomics) to reduced and selective application of neoliberal economic policy. The latter has ignored the Pareto principle and enabled the domination of uncontrolled and privileged economic freedoms over institutions (instead of complementarity of mass freedoms and institutions). This has led to the institutionalization of the privileges of rare (politically selected) individuals, procedural forms of domination and sophisticated forms of neototalitarianism, which imposed modern forms of social and economic "shackles" (development barriers).
Western authors distinguish between good and bad institutions (e.g., Rodrik, 2007), extractive and inclusive regimes (Acemoglu and Robinson, 2012), as well as limited access to resources and open access to resources (North, et al., 2009). In this way, they emphasize the objective conditions in which alternative institutions can exist and operate. Undoubtedly, the protection of property rights is the main factor, which serves to distinguish good institutions from bad institutions. North, et al. (Ibid.) noted and described in detail the existence of anti-competitive economic institutions in societies with limited access to resources. They attributed them to the conscious action of elites (especially those in government structures). Although they do not mention the existence and functioning of alternative institutions, they state and analyze in detail social violence, privileges, ballasts of feudalism, political rent-seeking, non-market redistribution, rule of law in favor of elites, and other negative social phenomena.
They conclude that the actions of the elites lead to the creation of violence in society (which is carried out precisely through the mechanism of alternative institutions - author's note). The institutional violence analyzed by the mentioned authors has the character of anti-institutional, and it comes from elites, and not from ordinary people (nations). This directly leads to redistributive effects, which benefit the ruling elites. Some Western authors emphasize the negative role of elites and government nomenclatures (Acemoglu, et al., 2004), as well as privileged individuals (Clark, 2009).
Figure no. 2 shows that the environment of alternative institutions is very complex, composed of diverse elements. However, what all these influencing factors have in common is the fact that they all stem from path dependency, while mostly derive from the behavior of the authorities. This is logical, given that the authorities are taking the initial impulse to create a system of alternative institutions, with their decision to abuse and subjugate formal and informal institutions for a long time.
In the period of the strongest waves of neoliberalism (more precisely: quasi-neoliberalism as an ideology of alternative institutions and a specific form of quasi-institutional monism), we criticized it sharply and argumentatively (hopefully competently), to the same extent as dirigisme (another polarized form of institutional monism). We have always advocated institutional pluralism, which objectively exists in various combinations in all developed countries. We have pointed out that every futile theorizing, which is aimed at any monistic glorification of a certain institutional order, is doomed to failure, because practice convincingly denies it.
In most so-called transition countries, the motivation of the reformers and the nomenclature of power have resulted in their enormous enrichment, which from the very beginning was accompanied by the strengthening of alternative institutions, quasiinstitutional violence, and appropriate control. All this was possible only in the conditions of immoral and obscure abuse of formal and informal institutions. The rhetoric on economic freedoms sounded demagogic, primitive, vulgar, and underestimating. It has led to their mass marginalization. As a result, abused liberalization dominated real institutional change and turned into quasi-institutionalization. Quasi-neoliberal macroeconomic recipes had a purely ideological character (a market mask for non-market appropriation).
Objectively, this could not create a healthy micro and macro economic environment, nor solve the problem of harmonizing the freedom of choice of individuals with collective interests. It was only a quasi-theoretical and ideological basis for the creation and strengthening of quasi-institutional monism, the natural result of which was the gradual and growing dominance of alternative institutions. In this way, real institutional changes were prevented, and they can be achieved only in the conditions of quality and legal institutional control, and institutional competition (key drivers of economic and social development). The dominance of alternative institutions has enabled the promotion of anti-institutional activities and the blockade of real institutional changes. Delibasic (2019) rightly states that many theoretical analyzes of institutional models have shown that socio-economic development includes not only economic factors (as a subsystem), but also a wide range of non-economic variables, including formal and informal institutions, cultural and other value systems, as well as all forms of opportunistic behavior, which have been established by alternative institutions (as a cultural-institutional subsystem).
In figure no. 3 we adapted the scheme created by Y. Hayami and Y. Godo (1997). We believe that this is completely justified when it comes to most post-socialist states, whose social system is very much created by alternative institutions, even more than legal (formal and informal) institutions.
Neoliberalism as the ideological foundation of alternative institutions in transition countries has failed to satisfy any element of the lowest common denominator of economic success: integration into the world economy, high labor mobility (Radukic, et al., 2019), large savings, significant investments, strengthening government competencies, commitment to economic development and social welfare, etc. Even the most liberal countries in the world are not in favor of an uncontrolled market, institutional monism, and non-market appropriation. Not to mention their extremely negative attitude towards quasi-institutional monism and the role of alternative institutions. If the former is true, then, clearly, underdeveloped countries cannot be dominated in global relations if developed countries recommend their own recipes to them. Late acknowledgments (M. Spence, A. Grispen, J. Williamson, etc.) after the 2008 global financial and economic crisis for misconceptions about free market efficiency seemed cynical.
Alternative institutions have an illegal, personified, socio-pathological, and destructive character. Their consequences are symptomatic and indicative. In that sense, it is necessary to analyze and explain the functional connection (relationship) of individuals and collectives, through the prism of their joint responsibility for creating favorable conditions for the emergence, operation, and strengthening of alternative institutions. We believe that the uncivilized, primitive, and dogmatic deformation of this relationship has significantly contributed to the institutional fiasco in many transition countries, resulting in the dominance of alternative institutions.
Institutional pluralism is a rational combination (synergy) of complementary conditioned individualistic and collectivist institutional actions, arrangements, efforts, and choices. It enables healthy and productive institutional competition. Ignoring institutional pluralism and forcing any form of institutional monism leads to the creation of a perverted individualism of interests (rare and privileged). During the transition period, quasi-neoliberal dogmas, utopias, and illusions about individualism were applied in many countries. They were methodologically, epistemologically (understood as the difference between truth and faith), and ontologically in constant (inevitable) conflict with neo-institutional economic theories and practices of developed countries, which promote institutional pluralism.
The mentioned monistic dogmas were based on the so-called market fundamentalism. That corresponded to the abstract, amoral, and unfounded story about the so-called minimal state. We have long ago proved the methodological unsustainability of this primitive, futile, vulgar, and orchestrated story, stating that it is not clear whether it refers to a social, economic, political or legal state?! Minimizing each of these state functions would realistically mean its collapse (Figure no. 4).
Unlimited quasi-neoliberal demagoguery and the dynamics of experimental deregulation have violated all moral and institutional limitations of economic reality and rational human behavior. As a result, reforms have not been successfully implemented in most transition countries. Government structures have decided to recombine institutions. This has directly and indirectly enabled the establishment of various forms of quasi-institutional relations. In fact, forcing of institutional monism (market type) has caused enormous consequences, the flourishing of uncontrolled market and non-market forms, and a protracted crisis. Such a factual situation is characterized by an insurmountable gap between repressed mass and privileged individualism, which exists in parallel with the growth of public debt, inefficient governance models, systemic corruption at all levels, pronounced social apathy and economic demotivation, and many other social costs caused by anti-development strategy.
Conclusion
This descriptive analysis has clearly shown that alternative institutions are the result of systemic and institutional fiasco, which in a paradoxical and organized way (through abuse and manipulation) enabled the domination of privileged elections, as well as interest-driven individualism over institutionalism. The alternative institutions are a weird transition child. Their domination over freedoms, knowledge, institutions, and truths is certainly the result of the influence of traditional culture and dogmatic thinking, susceptibility to some anachronistic cults, myths and prejudices, but also the actions of neoliberal ideology. To overcome them, it is necessary to accept the civilizational and pluralistic paradigm of development of humanistic type, as well as scientifically consistent and well-argued critiques of all monistic conceptions and illusions, especially neoliberal and dirigistic ones, which have always been an integral part of the braking mechanism, due to their restrictiveness and exclusivity.
Instead of individual greed and fraudulent neoliberal grail, socio-economic development must be sought in the civilizational adjustment - to political, economic, institutional, geopolitical, geo-economic, environmental, and etic norms. For decades, on all meridians, it has been lived on paradoxical and ironic consensus of fear, domination, blackmail, interests, stratification, division, integration, identity, greed, negative selection, apologetics and much more that confuses common sense. And all this under the thick and blurry layers of apparent democracy, doomed to betrayal by the dirigistic forces of power, alienated from the people (who elected them)!
For the success (sustainable development) of any country and/or nation, it is necessary to have a critical culture and humanistic thinking, rule of law, education, knowledge, science, institutions, patriotism, morality, freedom of choice, competition, control, transparency, security, solidarity, employment, work habits, entrepreneurship, private property on a mass scale, and innovation. Otherwise, the significant influence (and especially the dominance) of alternative institutions, opportunity and redistributive behavior, social pathology and all other traumatic trends, which are pointed out in this text - will not enable social and economic progress and will juristically lead to multiple crises.
Aggressive neoliberal values have been established for 30 years in society, economy and impersonal market, flooded with vanity, egoism, monism, ideology, politics, anachronism, monopoly, paradoxes and privileges. Freedom, democracy, sustainable development, rule of law, strong and efficient institutions, knowledge and other civilizational achievements, i.e. elimination of greedy nomenclatures of power and privileged abuse of state and people's interests are needed for a better, fairer and more humane order. This is the only way to realize in practice the acceptable world (term by H. Simon), which implies the parallel construction and improvement of the state and society.
Authors' ORCID:
Veselin Draskovic: orcid.org/0000-0003-3968-422X
Sergey A. Kravchenko: orcid.org/0000-0003-2528-5703
Milica Delibasic: orcid.org/0000-0003-1036-3836
Please cite this article as:
Draskovic, V., Kravchenko, S.A. and Delibasic, M., 2021. Synergy of Neoliberalism, Alternative Institutions and Transitional Crisis. Amfiteatru Economic, 23(57), pp.534-547.
Article History
Received: 14 November 2020
Revised: 30 January 2021
Accepted: 18 March 2021
Corresponding author, Veselin Draskovic - e-mail: [email protected]
References
Acemoglu, D. and Verdier, T., 2000. The choice between market failure and corruption. American Economic Review, 90(1), pp. 194-211.
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S. and Robinson, J., 2004. Institutions as the Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth. NBER Working Paper, No. 10481, Cambridge, MA, pp. 385-472.
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J.A., 2012. Why Nations Fail - the Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty. New York: Random House, Inc.
Alesina, A. and Gulisano, P., 2015. Culture and Institutions. Journal of Economic Literature, 53(4), pp. 898-944.
Allais, M., 1999. La mondialisation: la destruction des emplois et de la croissance; l'évidence empirique. Paris: Juglar.
Buchanan, J.M., 1990. The Domain of Constitutional Economics. Constitutional Political Economy, 1(1), pp. 1-18.
Buchanan, J.M., Robert, D.T. and Tullock, G. eds., 1980. Toward a Theory of the RentSeeking Society. College Station: Texas A&M University Press,.
Buchanan, JM. and Tullock, G., 1997. Calculus of Consent as the Logical Basis of Constitutional Democracy. in Nobel laureates in economics: Dzheyms B'yukenen, Moskow: Thaurus-Alfa, pp. 277-444 (in Russian).
Clark, G., 2009. A Farewell to Alms: A Brief Economic History of the World. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Congleton, R.D. and Hillman, A.L. eds., 2015. Companion to the political economy of rent seeking. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Delibasic, M., 2019. The Impact of Neoliberal Economic Policy on Economic Development in the Countries of Southeast Europe. Transformations in Business & Economics. 18(2 / 47, pp. 323-336.
Draskovic, V., 2018. Clokotrization of Transition - critical essays. Scezecin: Agharta Science Publishing House and Centre of Sociological Research.
Draskovic, V., 2020. New shackles: quasi-neoliberal violence of alternative institutions. Belgrade & Podgorica: Tipo Makarije & ELIT (in Serbian).
Draskovic, V., Draskovic, M. and Bilan, S., 2019. Motivation, Methodology, and Phenomenology of Institutional Nihilism in the SEE Countries. Montenegrin Journal of Economics, 15(2), pp. 7-14.
Draskovic, V., Jovovic, R., Streimikiene, D. and Bilan, S., 2020. Formal and Informal vs. Alternative Institutions. Montenegrin Journal of Economics, 16(2), pp. 193-201.
Evans, P., 1993. Rethinking on Embedded Autonomy. Berkley: University of California.
Goffman, E.A., 1968. Etudes sur la condition sociale des maladesmentaux et autres reclus. Paris: Les Editions de Minuit.
Hayami, Y. and Godo, Y., 1997. Development Economics: From the Poverty to the Wealth of Nations (Third Edition). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Horvathova, J. and Mokrisova, M., 2019. Business Competitiveness, its Financial and Economic Parameters. Montenegrin Journal of Economics, 16(1), pp. 139-153.
Kornai, J., 2002. System paradigm. Economic issues, 4, pp. 4-22 (in Russian).
Kravchenko, S.A., 2018. The becoming of non-linear knowledge: New risks, vulnerabilities and hopes. Montenegrin Journal of Economics, 14(4), pp. 191-202.
Kravchenko, S.A., 2014. A 'normal anomie': Contours of conception. Social studies, 8, pp. 3-10 (in Russian).
Kravchenko, S.A., 2020. The birth of 'normal trauma': The effect of non-linear development. Economic and Sociology, 13(2), pp. 150-159.
Krueger, A.O., 1974. The political economy of the rent-seeking society. American Economic Review, 64, pp. 291-303.
Marcouiller, D. and Young, L., 1995. The Black hole of graft: the predatory state and the informal economy. American Economic Review, 3, pp. 630-646.
Mc Auley, A., 1991. Market Failure Versus State Failure: the Scope for Privatization in a Planned Economy. Trento: Italy.
North, D., 1981. Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: W. W. Norton & Co.
North, D.C., Walis, J.J. and Weingast, B.R., 2009. Violence and Social Orders - A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History. Cambridge: The Syndicate of the Pres of the Cambridge University.
Olson, M., 2010. Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development. American Political Science Review, 87, pp. 567-576.
Panikarova, S., Vlasov, M. and Draskovic, M., 2020. Relationsheep Between Social Business Entrepreneurship and Business Freedom: an Evidence from the Russian. Montenegrin Journal of Economics, 16(3), pp.123-135.
Popovic, G., Eric, O. and Stanic, S., 2020. Trade Openness, Institutions and Economic Growth of the Western Balkans Countries. Montenegrin Journal of Economics, 16(3), pp.173-184.
Posner, R.A., 1975. The social cost of monopoly and regulation. Journal of Political Economy, 83, pp. 807-827.
Przeworski, A. and Limongi, F., 1993. Political Regimes and Economic Growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7(3), pp. 51-70.
Radukic, S., Mastilo, Z., Kostic, Z. and Ljubisa Vladusic, L., 2019. Measuring of The Goods and Labor Markets Efficiency: Comparative Study of Western Balkan Countries. Montenegrin Journal of Economics, 15(2), pp. 95-109.
Robinson, A.A., 1999. When is a State Predatory. CESifo Working Paper. 178, Munich: Center for Economic Studies and Ifo Institute (CESifo).
Rodrik, D., 2007. One economics, many recipes: globalization, institutions, and economic growth. Prinston: Prinston University Press.
Rose-Ackerman, S., 1999. Corruption and government, causes, consequences and reform, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Stojanov, D., 2013. Economic Crisis and Crisis of Economic Science. Rijeka: Faculty of Economica (in Croatian).
Tomas, R., 2000. The Limits of Neoliberal Globalization. Montenegrin Journal of Economics, 16(4), pp. 217-231.
Tullock, G., 1996. Corruption theory and practice. Contemporary Economic Policy, 14, pp. 6-13.
Williamson, O.E., 1985. Reflections on the new institutional economics. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 141(1), pp. 187-195.
Williamson, O. E., 1985a. The economic institutions of capitalism: Firms, markets, relational contracting. New York: The Free Press.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer
© 2021. This work is published under https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ (the “License”). Notwithstanding the ProQuest Terms and Conditions, you may use this content in accordance with the terms of the License.
Abstract
The subject of this paper is a critique of the quasi-neoliberal violence of alternative institutions, which are the most problematic and most threatening brake phenomenon of transition. They have been produced, strengthened and reproduced by the authorities of most post-socialist countries in the last three decades. The aim of this paper is to demystify neoliberalism, its ideological, philosophical, and monistic absolutizations, as well as quasi-neoliberal manifestations, which in many post-socialist countries were carried out directly under the auspices of alternative institutions. Also, the goal is to shed light on the causes of the long-term crisis, chaos, institutional violence, and lawlessness, and to enable the recognition of too visible (albeit blurred), rhetorical and "messianic" recipes, which are, in fact, developmental shackles. The paper is based on two hypotheses: first, that alternative institutions have abused and enslaved formal and informal institutions in most transition countries, which has led to numerous economic and social problems, including threats to the rule of law, freedoms, and civilizational development, and second, that a transitional hindering mechanism was created, which generated a neoexploitative, apologetic, neo-totalitarian and crisis environment. The paper uses common methods of social and economic sciences, including the methods of generalization, description, abstraction, comparison, induction and deduction. In conclusion, it is stated that the phenomenological identification and critical demystification of the interest connections and conditioning of neoliberalism, alternative institutions, and the crisis have been carried out, and that their exponents (alleged reformers and new elites) had an extremely negative impact on social, economic, scientific, educational, cultural and institutional development, because they degraded and destroyed them.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer
Details
1 University of Social Sciences, Poland; University of Montenegro, Montenegro
2 MGIMO-University, Moscow, Russia; Moscow State Institute of International Relations, MFA of Russia of Foreign Affairs of Russia (MGIMO-University), Moscow, Russia
3 University of Mediteranian, Podgorica, Montenegro