This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
1. Introduction
Portfolio optimization selection problem, well known as an essential topic in financial markets, has been done in deep researches by many scholars after the first reported by Markowitz [1]. The most frequently used method of optimal asset allocation strategies is HJB equation, i.e., the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation (see Detemple and Fernando [2], Björk et al. [3]). In the analysis of portfolio optimization, utility function and several system parameters are given to find the optimal values of the control parameters to realise the final utility maximization. Previous researches in this area are classified for the endogenous habit formation [2], the classic constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) by Yu and Yuan [4], the hyperbolic discounting [3], and the utilities like the mean-variance utility proposed by Li et al. [5]. In recent paper by Li et al. [6], the analytical solution portfolio optimization problem involving stochastic short-term interest rates is provided, which can be controlled by the mean-variance utility function with state dependent risk aversion (SDRA). The paper [6] uses the Nash equilibrium for the subgame strategy to concrete analytical expressions of value function and control policy of equilibrium and figure out under the condition of the stochastic short-term interest rates, how do investors with “natural risk aversion” achieve optimal control policies by simplifying financial settings.
Under the framework of mean variance equilibrium asset liability management with SDRA, some extended models have been constructed, such as the mean-variance asset-liability management problem by regime-switching models, as well as mean-variance models with only risky assets (see Bening and Koroley [7]; the asset-only models to asset-liability models have been greatly expanded by Yao et al. [8, 9]). A geometric method raised by Leippold et al. [10] is supposed to apply into the multiperiod mean-variance asset-liability management model by taking the implied mean-variance of liability frontier into consideration. A study by Chiu and Li [11] reported that the influence of the rebalancing frequency is quantified to determine the allocation of optimal initial funds. The work of extension into a continuous-time setting has been developed with the aid of a stochastic linear quadratic control approach. Based on the assumptions used in Leippold et al. [10], analytical results have been derived in a complete market with discussing the impact of liability on the optimal funding ratio. To construct more realistic models, more focus has been put on studying the asset-liability management under the market behavior in the face of many restriction conditions, for example, an uncertain investment horizon (see Li and Ng [12]; Li and Yao [13]), regime-switching to describe phenomena between “Bullish” and “Bearish” markets (see Elliott et al. [14]; Wei et al. [15]; Wu and Li [16]; Wu and Chen [17]; Yu [18]), the choice of optimal portfolio selection for assets with transaction costs without short sales (see Li et al. [19]), portfolio selection under partial information (see Xiong and Zhou [20]), bankruptcy control (see Li and Li [21]), jump-diffusion in financial markets (see Lim [22]; Zeng and Li [23]), and stochastic volatility and stochastic interest rates (see Lim [22]; Lim and Zhou [24]). Also, various studies of assets and liabilities management problem have been carried out in some particular field with application in insurance and pension fund, including Drijver [25] for pension funds Hilli et al. [26] for a Finnish pension company, and Gerstner et al. [27] and Chiu and Wong [28] for life insurance policies.
Among them, regime-switching models have become popular in finance and related fields, which is expected to describe the characteristics of different markets (called “Bullish” versus“Bearish”). A limited number of regimes have been applied to represent the various patterns of the market states. According to diverse financial markets as the change market pattern occurs, indices for instance the interest rate, appreciation rates, and volatilities of stock and liability may be different. Boyle and Draviam’s study [29] is an interesting example of regime-switching modelling applied in option pricing achieved by [29], followed by Elliott and Siu [30], who have embedded the regime-switching modelling into the bond valuation, the concept of which has been put forward in the portfolio selection problem by Zhou and Yin [31], Chen et al. [32], and Chen and Yang [33]. The research studied in [32, 33] involves both the asset-liability feature and Markovian regime-switching modelling. As we all know, the models with only risk assets are valuable to be studied. Yao et al. [8] were working on the research of the continuous-time mean-variance model for only risky assets. It is rare for risk-free asset in reality; as a matter of fact, a relatively long investment is considered, corresponding to the stochastic nature real interest rates and the inflation risk (see Viceira [34]). The previous method of a nominal risk-free asset incorporated into the market will simplify the process of selecting portfolio but degenerate the GMV strategy to a bank deposit strategy with zero risks, which is not favourable to investors. Besides, the empirical evidence in the study by DeMiguel et al. [35] shows that the static global minimum-variance (GMV) strategy with only risky assets (derived by Markowitz [1]) tends to be better in performance out-of-sample among all estimated optimal strategies. Then in general, the properties of the time-consistent MV strategies have been shown in a market only with risky assets by Chi [36] on the analysis of Yao et al. [8] and Zhang et al. [37].
In this paper, on the basis of the work of Björk et al. [3], it is determinate to make a further realistic financial model, and it makes sense to select a regime-switching market with only risky assets. Afterwards, the general expansion of the HJB equation will be reached according to the control theory with time inconsistency by Björk and Murgoci [38]. Finally, it proceeds the numerical illustrations to show our extended results and state the relationships with previous researches. The rest of the paper is completed as follows: the setting of the financial market will be explained in Section 2, with the developed structure of mean-variance asset-liability management with state-dependent risk aversion in a regime-switching market with only risky assets. Also, the HJB equation is generalized to the general situation. In Section 3, three different cases with derived solutions will be illustrated in details. More numerical examples are presented in Section 4 with corresponding figures and illustrations, and a conclusion is given in Section 5.
2. Model Formulation
In a given probability space filtered,
2.1. Financial Market
2.1.1. Assets
Suppose that an investor decides to allocate his wealth among
2.1.2. Wealth Process
It is assumed that an investor endowed with an initial wealth
To further simplify
We assume that all the functions are measurable and uniformly bounded in
2.1.3. Liability Process
In fact, the investor in the financial market is exposed to the uncontrollable liability, with value process by the following SDE:
Remark 1.
It is clearly to see the correlation between liability value and risky assets in the dynamic processes by
2.1.4. Surplus Process
Let
2.2. Mean-Variance Risky Asset Management (MVRAM)
First,
Second, let
Based on the analysis of Björk Bjrk and Murgoci [38], with the definition of equilibrium control in equation (9) and the infinitesimal generator
Theorem 1 (verification theorem).
It is assumed that
Moreover,
Proof.
On the basis of the HJB equation in [2] and the objective function [3], it can be derived as
When
Hence, equation (18) above can simply be represented as
So the expectations of the equation can be shown
After the process of iteration, we obtain
By substituting the results of (22) and (23) back into the equation of (21), we can get
Then
Through our proposed problem (16) with the definition of the control law in the classic work, it can be found out that the control
Thus, the optimization problem of (25) can be solved as
Here, by using the operator denotations of similarity, we have
The derivation of the extended HJB equation with stochastic volatility will be given as,
3. Solution Scheme
3.1. The Case with a Generated
Theorem 2.
Under the general form of states dependent risk aversion, the optimal control strategy of MVRAM among risky assets is
Proof.
By using the definition of the infinitesimal generator, we simplify and thus have
The resulting extended HJB equations can be rewritten as
Adding up all the terms related to
Therefore, the first-order condition for
3.2. The Case with a Natural Choice
Here, we have
Then, we make use of the following natural choice of
By differentiation, we have
Substituting the above expressions into
Then, we can simplify
By substituting these expressions into (32), we also have the following alternative expressions for
From equation (42), we can have the following system of ordinary differential equations (ODE):
By simplifying and substituting the expressions of
Following the process of simplification, the equilibrium control can be represented as (39)
3.3. The Case without Liability
By letting
The ODEs are still complicated, which requires to make a further restriction such that the first asset is risk-free, namely,
Then, it comes to the equilibrium value function as
4. Numerical Example
According to the research studied by Chen et al. [32] and Wei et al. [15], the market state is either “Bullish” or “Bearish” with the assumption of
4.1. The Case with Liability
Similarly, all the related constant parameters in situation two can been seen in Table 1, which are specified for the illustrative purpose.
Table 1
All the related constant parameters in the case with liability.
Parameter (symbol) | Regime 1 ( | Regime 2 ( |
Exit time ( | 10 | 10 |
Risk-free interest rate ( | 0.04 | 0.04 |
Risky asset appreciation rate ( | 0.2 | 0.05 |
Risky asset volatility ( | 0.3 | 0.07 |
Liability appreciation rate ( | 0.08 | 0.04 |
Liability volatility ( | 0.3 | 0.1 |
Differentiation of transition probabilities ( | 0.3 | 0.7 |
Risk aversion ( | 0.5 | 0.9 |
The corresponding ODE system becomes
4.2. The Case with a Natural Choice
Again, all the related constant parameters in situation three have been represented in Table 2. All parameters are specified for the illustrative purpose.
Table 2
All the related constant parameters in the case with a natural choice
Parameter (symbol) | Regime 1 ( | Regime 2 ( |
Exit time ( | 10 | 10 |
The first risky asset appreciation rate ( | 0.3 | 0.06 |
Other risky asset appreciation rate ( | 0.2 | 0.05 |
The first risky asset volatility ( | 0.3 | 0.07 |
Other risky asset volatility ( | 0.2 | 0.09 |
Liability appreciation rate ( | 0.08 | 0.04 |
Liability volatility ( | 0.3 | 0.1 |
Differentiation of transition probabilities ( | 0.3 | 0.7 |
Risk aversion ( | 0.5 | 0.9 |
The resulting ODE system are shown as follows:
4.3. The Case without Liability
All the related constant parameters in situation one have been displayed in Table 3, which are specified for the illustrative purpose.
Table 3
All the related constant parameters in the case without liability.
Parameter (symbol) | Regime 1 ( | Regime 2 ( |
Exit time ( | 10 | 10 |
Risk-free interest rate ( | 0.04 | 0.04 |
Risky asset appreciation rate ( | 0.2 | 0.05 |
Risky asset volatility ( | 0.3 | 0.07 |
Liability appreciation rate ( | 0.08 | 0.04 |
Liability volatility ( | 0.3 | 0.1 |
Differentiation of transition probabilities ( | 0.3 | 0.7 |
Risk aversion ( | 0.5 | 0.9 |
The ODE system of (56) can then be simplified in the form of the following expressions:
From Figures 1–6, in the “Bearish” market, we could see the optimal control strategy
[figure omitted; refer to PDF]
In Figures 7 and 8, they compare the results of optimal control strategy and the equilibrium value among three different situations under the “Bullish” market.
[figure omitted; refer to PDF]
In Figure 7, with the comparison of optimal control strategy (
In the last picture, the comparison has been made about the optimal control strategy by varying the risk aversion coefficient. The effect of the risk aversion has been analysed in Figure 9, which presents the optimal control strategy (
5. Conclusions
In this paper, the mean variance model of asset-liability management has been discussed in the case of state-dependent risk aversion with only risky assets. Based on the continuous-time Markov regime-switching, this paper derives an analytical optimal control expressions theoretically in a more realistic financial market and then makes numerical analysis on a series of special cases. From the numerical results, this paper reveals the feasibility and application of introducing factors, such as regime-switching, liability, and risky asset in a mean-variance optimization framework, and also shows the relationships between a set of risk aversions and the optimal controller.
Acknowledgments
This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China under Grant 71901222 and Grant 71974204. This work was supported in part by “the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities” and Zhongnan University of Economics and Law under Grant 2722020JX005.
[1] H. Markowitz, "Portfolio selection," The Journal of Finance, vol. 7 no. 1, pp. 77-98, DOI: 10.2307/2975974, 1952.
[2] J. B. Detemple, F. Zapatero, "Asset prices in an exchange economy with habit formation," Econometrica, vol. 59 no. 6, pp. 1633-1657, DOI: 10.2307/2938283, 1991.
[3] T. Björk, A. Murgoci, X. Y. Zhou, "Mean-variance portfolio optimization with state-dependent risk aversion," Mathematical Finance, vol. 24 no. 1,DOI: 10.1111/j.1467-9965.2011.00515.x, 2014.
[4] J. Yu, Y. Yuan, "Investor sentiment and the mean-variance relation," Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 100 no. 2, pp. 367-381, DOI: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.10.011, 2011.
[5] S. Li, C. Luong, F. Angkola, Y. Wu, "Optimal asset portfolio with stochastic volatility under the mean-variance utility with state-dependent risk aversion," Journal of industrial and management optimization, vol. 12 no. 4, pp. 1521-1533, DOI: 10.3934/jimo.2016.12.1521, 2016.
[6] S. Li, S. Liu, Y. Zhou, Y. Wu, X. Ge, "Optimal portfolio selection of mean-variance utility with stochastic interest rate," Journal of Function Spaces, vol. 2020,DOI: 10.1155/2020/3153297, 2020.
[7] V. E. Bening, V. Y. Korolev, Generalized Poisson Models and Their Applications in Insurance and Finance,DOI: 10.1515/9783110936018, 2002.
[8] H. X. Yao, Y. Z. Lai, Q. H. Ma, H. Zheng, "Characterization of efficient frontier for mean-variance model with a drawdown constraint," Applied Mathematics and Computation, vol. 220, pp. 770-782, DOI: 10.1016/j.amc.2013.07.009, 2013.
[9] H. X. Yao, Y. Z. Lai, Q. H. Ma, M. J. Jian, "Asset allocation for a DC pension fund with stochastic income and mortality risk: a multi-period mean-variance framework," Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, vol. 54, pp. 84-92, DOI: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2013.10.016, 2014.
[10] M. Leippold, F. Trojani, P. Vanini, "A geometric approach to multiperiod mean variance optimization of assets and liabilities," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, vol. 28 no. 6, pp. 1079-1113, DOI: 10.1016/S0165-1889(03)00067-8, 2004.
[11] M. C. Chiu, D. Li, "Asset and liability management under a continuous-time mean-variance optimization framework," Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, vol. 39 no. 3, pp. 330-355, DOI: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2006.03.006, 2006.
[12] D. Li, W. Ng, "Optimal dynamic portfolio selection: multiperiod mean-variance formulation," Mathematical Finance, vol. 10 no. 3, pp. 387-406, DOI: 10.1111/1467-9965.00100, 2000.
[13] H. X. Yao, Z. Li, S. Chen, "Continuous-time mean-variance portfolio selection with only risky assets," Economic Modelling, vol. 36, pp. 244-251, DOI: 10.1016/j.econmod.2013.09.041, 2014.
[14] R. J. Elliott, T. K. Siu, A. Badescu, "On mean-variance portfolio selection under a hidden Markovian regime-switching model," Economic Modelling, vol. 27 no. 3, pp. 678-686, DOI: 10.1016/j.econmod.2010.01.007, 2010.
[15] J. Wei, K. C. Wong, S. C. P. Yam, S. P. Yung, "Markowitz's mean-variance asset-liability management with regime switching: a time-consistent approach," Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, vol. 53 no. 1, pp. 281-291, DOI: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2013.05.008, 2013.
[16] H. Wu, Z. Li, "Multi-period mean-variance portfolio selection with regime switching and a stochastic cash flow," Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, vol. 50 no. 3, pp. 371-384, DOI: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2012.01.003, 2012.
[17] H. L. Wu, H. Chen, "Nash equilibrium strategy for a multi-period mean-variance portfolio selection problem with regime switching," Economic Modelling, vol. 46, pp. 79-90, DOI: 10.1016/j.econmod.2014.12.024, 2015.
[18] J. Yu, "Optimal asset-liability management for an insurer under Markov regime switching jump-diffusion market," Asia Pacific Financial Markets, vol. 21 no. 4, pp. 317-330, DOI: 10.1007/s10690-014-9187-6, 2014.
[19] Z. F. Li, Z. X. Li, S. Y. Wang, X. T. Deng, "Optimal portfolio selection of assets with transaction costs and no short sales," International Journal of Systems Science, vol. 32 no. 5, pp. 599-607, DOI: 10.1080/00207720119100, 2001.
[20] J. Xiong, X. Y. Zhou, "Mean-variance portfolio selection under partial information," SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, vol. 46 no. 1, pp. 156-175, DOI: 10.1137/050641132, 2007.
[21] C. Li, Z. Li, "Multi-period portfolio optimization for asset-liability management with bankrupt control," Applied Mathematics and Computation, vol. 218 no. 22, pp. 11196-11208, DOI: 10.1016/j.amc.2012.05.010, 2012.
[22] A. E. B. Lim, "Quadratic hedging and mean-variance portfolio selection with random parameters in an incomplete market," Mathematics of Operations Research, vol. 29 no. 1, pp. 132-161, DOI: 10.1287/moor.1030.0065, 2004.
[23] Y. Zeng, Z. F. Li, "Asset-liability management under benchmark and mean-variance criteria in a jump diffusion market," Journal of Systems Science and Complexity, vol. 24 no. 2, pp. 317-327, DOI: 10.1007/s11424-011-9105-1, 2011.
[24] A. E. B. Lim, X. Y. Zhou, "Mean-variance portfolio selection with random parameters in a complete market," Mathematics of Operations Research, vol. 27 no. 1, pp. 101-120, DOI: 10.1287/moor.27.1.101.337, 2002.
[25] S. Drijver, Asset Liability Management for Pension Funds Using Multistage Mixedinteger Stochastic Programming, 2005.
[26] P. Hilli, M. Koivu, T. Pennanen, A. Ranne, "A stochastic programming model for asset liability management of a Finnish pension company," Annals of Operations Research, vol. 152 no. 1, pp. 115-139, DOI: 10.1007/s10479-006-0135-3, 2007.
[27] T. Gerstner, M. Griebel, M. Holtz, R. Goschnick, M. Haep, "A general asset-liability management model for the efficient simulation of portfolios of life insurance policies," Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, vol. 42 no. 2, pp. 704-716, DOI: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2007.07.007, 2008.
[28] M. C. Chiu, H. Y. Wong, "Mean-variance asset-liability management: cointegrated assets and insurance liability," European Journal of Operational Research, vol. 223 no. 3, pp. 785-793, DOI: 10.1016/j.ejor.2012.07.009, 2012.
[29] P. Boyle, T. Draviam, "Pricing exotic options under regime switching," Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, vol. 40 no. 2, pp. 267-282, DOI: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2006.05.001, 2007.
[30] R. J. Elliott, T. K. Siu, "On Markov-modulated exponential-affine bond price formulae," Applied Mathematical Finance, vol. 16 no. 1,DOI: 10.1080/13504860802015744, 2009.
[31] X. Y. Zhou, G. Yin, "Markowitz’s mean-variance portfolio selection with regime switching: a continuous-time model," SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization, vol. 42 no. 4, pp. 1466-1482, DOI: 10.1137/S0363012902405583, 2003.
[32] P. Chen, H. L. Yang, G. Yin, "Markowitz's mean-variance asset-liability management with regime switching: a continuous-time model," Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, vol. 43, pp. 456-465, DOI: 10.1016/j.insmatheco.2008.09.001, 2008.
[33] P. Chen, H. L. Yang, "Markowitz’s mean-variance asset-liability management with regime switching: a multi-period model," Applied Mathematical Finance, vol. 18 no. 1, pp. 29-50, DOI: 10.1080/13504861003703633, 2011.
[34] L. M. Viceira, "Bond risk, bond return volatility, and the term structure of interest rates," International Journal of Forecasting, vol. 28 no. 1, pp. 97-117, DOI: 10.1016/j.ijforecast.2011.02.018, 2012.
[35] V. DeMiguel, L. Garlappi, F. J. Nogales, R. Uppal, "A generalized approach to portfolio optimization: improving performance by constraining portfolio norms," Management Science, vol. 55 no. 5, pp. 798-812, DOI: 10.1287/mnsc.1080.0986, 2009.
[36] S. P. Chi, "Time-consistent mean-variance portfolio selection with only risky assets," Economic Modelling, vol. 75, pp. 281-292, 2018.
[37] M. Zhang, F. Chen, H. X. Yao, "Mean-variance portfolio selection with only risky assets under regime switching," Economic Modelling, vol. 62, pp. 35-42, DOI: 10.1016/j.econmod.2016.12.030, 2017.
[38] T. Björk, A. Murgoci, "A theory of Markovian time-inconsistent stochastic control in discrete time," Finance and Stochastics, vol. 18 no. 3, pp. 545-592, DOI: 10.1007/s00780-014-0234-y, 2014.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer
Copyright © 2021 Shuang Li et al. This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License (the “License”), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. Notwithstanding the ProQuest Terms and Conditions, you may use this content in accordance with the terms of the License. https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/
Abstract
How do investors require a distribution of the wealth among multiple risky assets while facing the risk of the uncontrollable payment for random liabilities? To cope with this problem, firstly, this paper explores the approach of asset-liability management under the state-dependent risk aversion with only risky assets, which has been considered under a continuous-time Markov regime-switching setting. Next, based on this realistic modelling, an extended Hamilton-Jacob-Bellman (HJB) system has been necessarily established for solving the optimization problem of asset-liability management. It has been derived closed-form analytical expressions applied in the time-inconsistent investment with optimal control theory to see that happens to the optimal value of the function. Ultimately, numerical examples presented with comparisons of the analytical results under different market conditions are exposed to analyse numerically the developed mean variance asset liability management strategy. We find that our proposed model can explain the financial phenomena more effectively and accurately.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer
Details




1 Department of Mathematics and Physics, Mianyang Normal University, Mianyang 621000, China
2 Department of Mathematics and Statistics, Curtin University, Perth, WA 6102, Australia
3 School of Finance, Zhongnan University of Economics and Law, Wuhan 430073, China
4 School of Statistics and Mathematics, Zhongnan University of Economics and Law, Wuhan 430073, China