This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
1. Introduction
With the rapid increase in the environmental awareness of the general public, many firms are well devoted to producing green products partly for developing a green economy and improving eco-environment in different industries around the world. These green products include the electric cars produced by American car-maker Tesla, the fluorine-free air conditioner made by Japanese home appliance manufacturer Panasonic, and others [1–4]. In addition to these manufacturing producers, some leading retailers are also engaged in the investment and promotion of green products. For example, one of the giant home appliance retailers in the world, Best Buy, sells ENERGY STAR-certified products to help businesses and consumers save money and protect our climate through superior energy efficiency.
Transforming from producing a regular product to a green one requires a large amount of capital, including product design, product publicity, and technological innovation. Hence, the capital constraint may constitute a major obstacle restricting this transformation of the firms, especially for the small and medium-sized ones, which always suffers from the financial difficulties even during regular operations. To ease the capital shortage, the firms can borrow loans to invest in green innovation, and the most common way is to finance from Bank. For example, by the end of 2021, 15 major banks in China have issued a total of 220.3 billion carbon emission reduction loans, supporting 2,246 projects to assist enterprises in producing low-carbon products [5]. Inevitably, the capital-constrained firms will pay additional costs to raise the capital, such as paying the interest to the lender, which in turn affects its operation and the associated performance. Hence, an interesting issue has arisen here to reveal how the financing affects the firm’s selling and greening operation.
Nowadays, especially during the COVID-19 epidemic, online retailing has gradually become a mainstream alternative for the firms to distribute their various products [6, 7]. It is noticed from the industrial practice that the two complementary online channel modes are available for the firms to sell the products with an online marketplace, i.e., one is online agency channel and the other is online reselling channel. In terms of the online agency mode, the firm directly sells the products to the end consumers, paying commission sales to the e-commerce platform as the revenue share. In this case, the firm takes the ownership over the products, and the platform just serves as an online marketplace. By contrast, with the online reselling mode, the seller first wholesales products to the platform, and after that, the platform retails the products to end consumers. Under this circumstance, the platform takes the ownership over products and thus acts as an online reseller. The conventional wisdom suggests that the online agency mode will mitigate the double-marginalization effect and may require a low capital level to cover production. Therefore, the online channel mode will induce a significant impact on the financing decisions. Given different features of the two online channel modes, the two online channel modes will pose a key role in the operation decisions of the members, thereby decreasing or increasing the individual profits with an e-commerce platform supply chain. Herein, an interesting issue has arisen to explore the optimal online channel mode for the individuals with this e-commerce platform supply chain.
As a matter of fact, different individuals may act contradictorily when selecting the online channel modes. Essentially, it is the bargaining power among different individuals that finally determines the online channel mode selection between the individuals. Thus, it is worth investigating how the channel leaderships between the individuals affect the optimal online channel mode selection as well as the individual surplus, such as consumer and social community.
Motivated by the previous industrial practice, this paper develops an e-commerce supply chain consisting one platform and one capital-constrained manufacturer with two different online channel modes, in which the capital-constrained manufacturer chooses bank loan to ease capital shortage. To be specific, the main research questions of this paper are addressed as follows:
(i) How does the financing affect the operation and the individual profits with an e-commerce platform supply chain?
(ii) When should the individual select the online agency mode and when should it select the online reselling mode instead?
(iii) What are the impacts of the channel leadership on the consumer surplus and the social welfare?
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2 reviews the most related literature. The problem descriptions are explicitly exhibited in Section 3, followed by which we develop an e-commerce supply chain system with the online agency mode in Section 4 and with the online reselling mode in Section 5, respectively. By comparing the equilibrium profits across two different online channel modes, Section 6 further investigates the optimal online channel mode selections for the manufacturer and the platform, respectively. This paper extends to a supply chain with a different leaderships and discusses the impacts of the consumer surplus and the social welfare on the two different supply chains in Section 7. Section 8 concludes the key findings with the managerial insights and future researches. For clarity, all proofs of the results are collected together in the Appendix.
2. Literature
The literature closely related to this paper is threefold, namely, green supply chain, supply chain finance, and online channel mode selection.
2.1. Green Supply Chain
As the increasing pressure of the environmental protection, the governmental regulation, and the continuous development in green product, green supply chain design and management has gradually become an environmentally sustainable strategy for the supply chain decision-makers and has thus been paid notable attention in academia.
A large number of studies in the green supply chain mainly focus on the green innovation and operational decisions. Chen and Sheu [8] apply a differential game model to demonstrate that a proper design of environment-regulation pricing strategy can boost the extended product responsibility for green supply chain, especially in a highly competitive market. Bhaskaran and Krishnan [9] propose various mechanisms of collaboration between two firms in the development of green products yielding technology uncertainty. Ghosh and Shah [10] examine the green investment in an apparel serial supply chain in which the players cooperate or act individually. Li et al. [11] explore a dual-channel supply chain where the manufacturer produces green products for the environmental conscious and investigate the joint pricing and greening strategies for the chain members in both centralized and decentralized cases. Meng et al. [12] use game theory to analytically explore the pricing policy in a green supply chain of a dual-channel structure, in which consumers’ green preference and channel preference are considered. Huang et al. [1] investigate the optimal green and pricing strategies in a capital-constrained supply chain with different governmental green subsidies. Das Roy and Sana [13] examine a multiechelon green supply chain system in which a traditional production process is integrated with a remanufacturing in a single-setup-multidelivery system under setup cost reduction. Liu et al. [14] study how the retailer’s fairness concern levels affect the cooperation in a three-stage sustainable supply chain. Sana [15] look into a newsvendor inventory problem where comparisons between green and nongreen marketing are explicitly analyzed including subsidy and tax implementation by the governmental regulation.
2.2. Supply Chain Finance
Capital shortage has always been a most important issue that the firms suffer from during the production and operation process, especially for those small and medium ones. Financing is an effective way for those capital-constrained firms to deal with the capital shortage and thus has drawn much attention in academic studies by scholars.
Chen and Cai [16] look into an extended supply chain model with a supplier, a budget-constrained retailer, a bank, and a 3PL firm, where the retailer has insufficient initial budget and can borrow loans from either a bank or a 3PL firm. Cai et al. [17] investigate the roles of bank and trade credits in a supply chain with a capital-constrained retailer yielding demand uncertainty. Zhang et al. [18] propose a portfolio financing strategy of bank loan financing and retailer credit financing for a closed-loop supply chain consisting of a financially constraint manufacturer and a retailer. Jin et al. [19] develop a proper financing scheme and discuss its efficiency of supplier intermediation in retailer financing in the case of unreliable products. Yan et al. [20] examine a dual-channel supply chain where the retailer and e-commerce platform can freely use the other’s sales efforts and the e-commerce platform can provide online finance services to the capital-constrained supplier. Zheng et al. [21] consider a remanufacturing supply chain in which the retailer is capital-constrained and examine the optimal financing decision in terms of the market uncertainty. Sana et al. [22] discuss the operational and financial decisions among the supply chain individuals including one manufacturer and one distributor. Yan et al. [23] introduce supplier finance and supplier investment to a capital-constrained supply chain in which the retailer is subject to a capital constraint and investigate the impacts of retailer’s loss aversion on the supply chain financing decisions.
2.3. Online Channel Mode Selection
In recent years, the online selling has been paid notable attention in supply chain management. Extended studied focusing on this research stream mainly includes the following aspects, such as competition and cooperation [6, 24], information disclosure [25–27], return policy [28–30], online reviews [31–33], interactions of online and offline channels [34, 35], and online value-add services [36, 37].
Specifically, this paper contributing to this research stream lies in the optimal online channel modes in an e-commerce platform supply chain. It is well noticed that the two online channel modes, i.e., the agency mode and the reselling mode, are typically adopted by the e-commerce platform to their upstream suppliers. Hence, the most related researching line of this stream in regards to the online channel mode is to identify the optimal online channel mode for the different individuals and reveal the key drivers behind deriving this strategic online channel mode selections. For example, Tian et al. [6] indicate how to select a better online channel mode for an e-commerce platform based on which the two competing suppliers sell the complementary products through the platform. Qin et al. [36] look into the interplay of the logistics service provision and online channel mode and focus on how the logistics service strategy affect the optimal online channel mode selection in a platform supply chain. Zhang and Zhang [38] study the e-tailer information sharing strategy with supplier offline entry in which the e-tailer can choose either online agency channel or online reselling channel. Chen et al. [39] investigate the optimal online channel mode for an e-seller and explore who is better off to offer the return-freight insurance in a platform supply chain. Yu et al. [40] explore a manufacturer’s production decisions and a government’s choice between cap-and-trade and carbon tax regulation in which the manufacturer sells the product through offline and online channels where the online channel can be the reselling mode or the agency mode. Zhang et al. [41] investigate how to select an optimal online channel mode for a manufacturer in an e-commerce platform supply chain in the presence of a secondary marketplace. Wang et al. [42] consider a multiple echelon supply chain where an upstream supplier can retail its products through an online e-commerce platform and a live streaming sales channel, and the online platform company can choose the reselling channel mode or the agency channel mode.
This paper contributes to the literature from the following aspects: Firstly, this paper focuses on the joint financing and green decisions in a capital-constrained platform supply chain. The aim of this paper is to investigate the mutual impacts of financing and operational decision in this platform supply chain. Secondly, in contrast to the existing studies on the optimal online channel mode selection in an e-commerce supply chain with sufficient capital, the fundamental difference of this paper lies in the fact that this paper explicitly selects the optimal online channel mode for the two parties when the manufacturer is subject to the capital constraint.
For better exhibiting the key differences between this paper and the most related literature, Table 1 thus formulates.
Table 1
Positioning of this paper in the literature.
Paper | Green product | Financing | Channel mode | Channel leadership | Consumer surplus | Social welfare |
Ghosh and Shah [10] | ||||||
Li et al. [11] | ||||||
Huang et al. [1] | ||||||
Zheng et al. [21] | ||||||
Zhang et al. [18] | ||||||
Zhang et al. [41] | ||||||
[43] | ||||||
Zhang et al. [7] | ||||||
Our work |
3. Model Formulation
We consider an e-commerce platform supply chain consisting of an e-platform and a capital-constrained manufacturer. It is well noticed from the industrial practice that the platform typically provides two options with their manufacturer to sell products [6, 7, 39], that is, the capital-constrained manufacturer has two choices to sell the green product via the platform’s online marketplace; one is the online reselling mode and the other is the online agency mode. In terms of the reselling mode, the manufacturer wholesales the products to the platform at wholesale price
To encourage green product development, the capital-constrained manufacturer invests in green R & D technology, and the green effort is denoted as
On the market side, it is well noticed that consumers are willing to purchase the green products because of their high greenness and lower environmental damages. The greener the product , the more the consumers will pay for it. This paper applies a linear demand function to capture such a phenomenon by following the related literature [1, 44, 45], such as
The capital-constrained manufacturer faces financing obstacles when producing the green products. The marginal cost of a unit product for the manufacturer is
For eases of exposition and clarity, the notation used in this paper can be found in Table 2.
Table 2
List of notations.
Parameters | |
The market potential | |
The consumer’s sensitivity to the environmental awareness | |
The resulting demand of the product | |
The cost factor when the manufacturer invests in green technology | |
The marginal cost of a unit product | |
The initial capital of the capital-constrained manufacturer | |
The interest rate set by bank | |
The commission. With the online agency mode, the capital-constrained manufacturer pays a sales commission | |
The capital-constrained manufacturer pays the slotting fee | |
Consumer surplus | |
Social welfare | |
Decision variables | |
The wholesale price of the product when the capital-constrained manufacturer selects the online reselling mode | |
The retail price of the product with the both reselling and agency modes | |
The green effort of the manufacturer |
4. Reselling Mode-Scenario R
With the reselling mode, the manufacturer produces the product with green degree
Applying the backward induction, the equilibrium decisions are achieved in Proposition 1.
Proposition 1.
With the reselling mode, the equilibrium decisions are given by
According to Proposition 1, the resulting demand for the product is
Corollary 1.
With the reselling mode, the impacts of the interest rate on the equilibriums and individual profits are as follows:
(i)
(ii) if
(iii) if
(iv)
In the previous corollary,
It is seen from Corollary 1 that the product’s greenness, the resulting market demand, and the individual profits of the manufacturer and the platform decrease with an increase in the interest rate. This phenomenon is naturally understandable that with an increase in the financing rate, the associated financing cost also increases. Therefore, the manufacturer has to reduce investments in the product’s greenness by balancing the production amount and the financing cost, which results in a decrease of the resulting demand. Also, it is obvious that an increase in the interest rate signifies that bank extracts more profits from the entire supply chain. Consequently, the two individuals will obtain less profits with a higher interest rate set by bank.
Corollary 1 also indicates how the interest rate affects the wholesale and retail prices, which is largely relied on the specific interest rate. To be specific, an increase in the interest rate first decreases the wholesale and retail prices and then increases the wholesale and retail prices. On the one hand, when the interest rate is relatively small as
It is obvious to verify that
5. Agency Mode-Scenario A
With the agency mode, by paying a slotting fee and commission sales to the platform, the manufacturer takes the ownership over products and directly retails them to the end consumers via the platform’s online marketplace. Similarly, the profit functions of the platform and the manufacturer are respectively achieved as follows:
It is noticed from the industrial practice that the e-platform publicly and advancingly declares the commissions in response to the product categories for all the potential suppliers every year. For example, JD.com offers and updates the commissions in response to every product category for any potential suppliers [46]. Thus, this paper considers an exogenous commission. Such an assumption can also be seen in the related literature, such as [47, 48] and [6]. Hence, the equilibrium decisions and the individual profits can be obtained in Proposition 2.
Proposition 2.
With the agency mode, the equilibrium decisions are given by
Based on Proposition 2, the resulting demand with the agency mode is achieved as
Corollary 2.
With the agency mode, the impacts of the commission on the equilibriums are obtained as follows:
(i)
(ii)
(iii)
Corollary 2 clearly indicates the impacts of the commission on the greenness, retail price, and the resulting demand. It is seen that with a higher commission, the manufacturer will pay more sales to the platform. Naturally, the manufacturer reduces investments in green technology and charges a higher retail price to balance its profit and the revenue share to the platform. Also, the greenness and the retail price of the product play a comprehensive effect on the resulting demand, and it signifies that the negative impact of the greenness on the demandand it signifies that the negative effect caused by the greenness on the demand is much more to balance the positive one caused by the retail price on the demand.
6. Online Channel Mode Selection
In this section, we investigate the optimal online channel mode for the manufacturer and the platform, which is shown in Propositions 3 and 4, respectively.
Proposition 3.
The manufacturer will choose the agency mode under the following circumstance and will choose the reselling mode otherwise, such that
It is noticed from Proposition 3 that the commission rate and the slotting fee jointly play a key role in the manufacturer’s optimal online channel mode selection. Herein, we can verify that an increase in either the commission rate or the slotting fee will shift the manufacturer to choose the reselling mode. This is understandable that the manufacturer will pay more sales to the platform with the agency mode when the platform sets a higher commission or a higher slotting fee. Consequently, the manufacturer will turn to the reselling mode instead when suffering a relatively high commission rate or/and a higher slotting fee. The impacts of other key factors on this selection are more complexed, and we apply the numerical experiments to graphically show such effects derived by the interest rate and product cost in the following part.
In the practice, the manufacturer typically decides which online channel is to be selected for its products’ sale through the platform’s online marketplace. However, to a certain extent, the platform poses more powers over the manufacturer on such type of decision-making, such as pricing and channel distribution and among others. Hence, it is necessary to compare the platform’s profit across these two different online channel modes, so as to reach an advantage outcome that satisfies both the manufacturer and the platform.
Next, we investigate the optimal online channel mode for the platform, which is shown in Proposition 4.
Proposition 4.
The platform will choose the agency mode under the following circumstance and will choose the reselling mode otherwise, such that
Similarly, Proposition 3 reveals the optimal online channel mode selection for the platform. It is easy to verify that a higher slotting fee will push the platform to choose the agency mode. However, the impact of the commission rate on the platform’s selection is more comprehensive, and we apply the numerical experiments to show how the commission affects the platform’s optimal online channel selection. By following the literature [3, 49–51] and setting the parameters
[figure(s) omitted; refer to PDF]
Obviously, based on Proposition 3 and 4, we can infer that both the manufacturer and the platform will likely choose the same online channel mode to sell the product under certain market conditions. To graphically show this advantage situation satisfying the two parties, Figure 1(c) indicates that when the platform sets a moderate commission, both the manufacturer and the platform will reach an agreement and choose the agency mode. The win-win situation herein holds for the two parties. Also, it signifies that the win-win situation will purely exist when both the manufacturer and the platform choose the agency mode. Furthermore, a higher commission along with a low slotting fee is constructive for the two parties to reach the win-win situation and vice versa.
The following applies the numerical experiments to further reveal the other key factors behind to derive this selection. Figures 2 and 3 investigate the impacts of the interest rate and the product cost on the optimal online channel mode selection, respectively.
[figure(s) omitted; refer to PDF]
Letting Figure 1 be a benchmark, when facing a relatively low interest rate, it is seen that both the manufacturer and the platform will likely choose the agency mode, given a commission rate and a slotting fee. Hence, the region of the win-win situation becomes large in this case as shown in Figure 2(c). This clearly indicates that a sufficiently low interest rate will push both the manufacturer and the platform, which will reach an agreement and choose the agency mode. Similarly, it is seen form Figure 3 that an increase in the product cost will shift the manufacturer to choose the reselling mode and platform to select the agency mode. Obviously, this kind of transforming on the online channel mode selection for the two parties will narrow the region of the win-win situation as shown in Figure 3(c).
7. Extension and Discussion
This section firstly extends to a supply chain with a reverse channel leadership in which the manufacturer acts as the leader and the platform is the follower and then explores and compares the consumer surplus and the social welfare across different business scenarios.
7.1. Extension to a Supply Chain with Different Leadership
It is noticed that the platform generally poses more bargaining powers over the most manufacturers in controlling the retailing channel and consumers’ preferences. However, some leading manufacturers with big brand names may have more powers when bargaining with the platform to a certain extent. In this subsection, we consider a situation in which the manufacturer acts as a Stackelberg leader and the platform is the follower. Parallel to Sections 4 and 5, the two different scenarios are, respectively, referred as Scenario
Proposition 5.
With the reselling mode, the equilibrium decisions are given by
Clearly, when the manufacturer acts as the Stackelberg leader with the online agency mode, the equilibrium decisions and the profits are the same as those given in Section 4. To focus on the online channel mode selection for two parties, the following continues to investigate the optimal online channel mode for the manufacturer and the platform, which is shown in Proposition 6 and Proposition 7, respectively.
Proposition 6.
With a different supply chain leadership, the manufacturer will choose the agency mode under the following circumstance and will choose the reselling mode otherwise, such that
Parallel to the associated channel mode selections, when the platform acts a leader, Propositions 6 and 7 reveal how to select the optimal online channel mode when the manufacturer serves as a leader. That is, the slotting fee and the commission induce a similar pattern on the effects of the optimal online channel mode for the two parties, which is not elaborated here. Similarly, the following applies the numerical experiments to focus on the other key factors behind to derive this selection.
Proposition 7.
With a different supply chain leadership, the platform will choose the agency mode under the following circumstance and will choose the reselling mode otherwise, such that
It is seen from Figure 4 that both the slotting fee and the commission induce a similar effect on the optimal online channel mode for the two parties when the manufacturer acts as a leader. To be specific, an increase in the slotting fee and/or the commission will shift the manufacturer to choose the reselling mode yet shift the platform to choose the agency mode. Additionally, a mild commission with an appropriate slotting fee will pose an advantage selection for two parties, where both the manufacturer and the platform select the agency mode.
[figure(s) omitted; refer to PDF]
Furthermore, from Figures 5 and 6, we know that a low interest rate set by bank is likely to derive a win-win situation for the two parties, and a higher product cost will exacerbate the differences between manufacturer and platform on the online channel mode selection.
[figure(s) omitted; refer to PDF]
Combining with Section 6, we know that both the slotting fee and the commission will move the manufacturer and the platform toward different directions on the online channel selection, regardless of the different supply chain leaderships. No matter who leads the supply chain, the platform and the manufacturer will reach a win-win situation when the commission becomes moderate along with an appropriate slotting fee. In the case of the win-win situation, the platform and the manufacturer are willing to choose the agency mode.
7.2. Discussion to the Consumer Surplus and the Social Welfare
Consumer surplus reflects the amount of utility or gain that customers receive when they buy products and services. By designing and developing a green product, consumer surplus is very important for the firms to consider, because consumers that derive a large benefit from buying products are more likely to purchase the green products again in the future. In practice, when the firms make such type of operational decisions, they not only care about their own profits but also take their shareholders’ profit into account. As a main stakeholder in the supply chain, consumers have become a key focus of firms in making decisions. This subsection shall next consider how the consumer surplus and the social welfare affect the individual’s optimal online channel mode selection in this platform supply chain. By following the literature [52, 53], we measure the consumer surplus as given by
Herein, the social welfare for the supply chain is obtained as follows:
Based on the associated equilibrium decisions and individual profit, it is easy to compute the consumer surplus and the social welfare, respectively. Furthermore, we compare the consumer surplus and the social welfare across two different supply chain leaderships.
It is seen from Figure 7 that the relative consumer surplus across the two online channel modes relies largely on the commission. To be specific, when the commission is relatively low, the agency mode will benefit the consumers and thus the consumers will obtain more surpluses. Otherwise, the reselling mode is meaningful to boost the consumer surplus when the commission is sufficiently high. This is understandable that when the commission is very low, the manufacturer will naturally pay less revenue to the platform and thus determine a relatively low retail price, thereby stimulating the consume surplus. In addition, we find that the slotting fee exerts no effect on the relative consumer surplus with the two different supply chains with different channel leaderships. The reason behind is that the slotting fee is a fixed revenue that distributes between the platform and the manufacturer, which does not affect the retail prices.
[figure(s) omitted; refer to PDF]
Figure 8 clearly reveals the relative social welfare across the two online channel modes with the two supply chains with different channel leaderships. Similarly, we find that the slotting fee has no effects on the relative social welfare, and the relative social welfare is highly relied on the commission. In particular, the agency mode with a lower commission will benefit the social welfare, mostly compared with the reselling mode. This indicates that when the supply chain concerns more about the social welfare, the platform will pay a relatively low commission to the manufacturers.
[figure(s) omitted; refer to PDF]
Next, we investigate how the interest rate affects the relative consumer surplus and social welfare across different online channel modes and supply chain leaderships. It is seen from Figures 9 and 10 that an increase in the interest rate signifies that the supply chain will enjoy a higher social welfare with more consumer surpluses with the reselling mode. This indicates that when the capital-constrained manufacturer suffers a relatively high interest rate set by bank, it is optimal for the platform supply chain to choose the reselling mode to achieve a better performance in both consumer surplus and the social welfare.
[figure(s) omitted; refer to PDF]
8. Conclusions
This paper develops an e-commerce platform supply chain that consists of one platform company and one capital-constrained manufacturer. By borrowing the loans from bank, the capital-constrained manufacturer can raise sufficient capital to produce and sell the products through the platform’s online marketplace with either the online agency channel mode or the online reselling channel mode. The focal point of this paper is to, respectively, investigate the optimal online channel mode for the manufacturer and the platform. The current work also extends to a different supply chain with a different leadership, based on which we explore the impacts of supply chain leaderships on the consumer surplus as well as the social welfare.
8.1. Key Findings
With the analytical study, the key findings of this paper are collected as follows:
Firstly, we find that the initial capital level has no effect on the equilibrium decisions of the two supply chain members but largely affect the manufacturer’s profit with two different online channel modes. It is the interest rate that plays a critical role in determining the respective equilibrium decisions.
Secondly, the optimal online channel mode selections for the manufacturer and the platform are, respectively, investigated and the factors behind deriving these strategic selections are also revealed. It clearly exhibits that an increase in either commission or the slotting fee will make the manufacturer and platform act differently in selecting the optimal online channel mode, that is, the manufacturer will choose the online reselling mode, while the platform will select the online agency mode. Interestingly, we find that the manufacturer and the platform will reach a consensus and choose the online agency mode to achieve a win-win situation under certain market conditions.
Finally, this paper compares the supply chain performances from different perspectives. The impacts of different online channel modes on the consumer surplus and social welfare are explored with different supply chain leaderships. It is found that the commission plays a key role in the relative consumer surplus and social welfare whereas the slotting fee has no such effects on them. The supply chain performs better in both the consumer surplus and social welfare with the reselling mode when bank sets a relatively high interest rate.
8.2. Managerial Implications
Based on the key findings derived in this paper, herein, the contributions to the industrial practice are collected in the following:
Firstly, considering a situation that the green product manufacturer may suffer the capital shortage, this paper incorporates two different online channel modes to an e-commerce platform supply chain with the capital-constrained manufacturer selecting bank loan financing. We explicitly reveal the impacts of the financing on the equilibrium decisions and individual profits. Managerial implications for firms on selecting the optimal online channel mode are obtained, based on which we find a win-win situation benefiting the two parties when choosing the online agency mode under certain market conditions. This results compliment the existing studies on the online channel mode selection [6, 7, 54].
Secondly, this paper then reveals how the different supply chain leaderships affect the individual profits and consumer surplus as well as social welfare. It is well noticed that the commission set by the platform plays a crucial role in determining the relative consumer surplus and social welfare, whereas the slotting fee has no such effects on them across the two different online channel modes. The supply chain will perform better in both consumer surplus and social welfare when applying the online reselling mode along with facing a relatively high interest rate set by bank. This provides managerial insights for industrial practicer on how to effectively make such decision-making in platform economy.
8.3. Limitations and Further Research
The following summarizes the limitations and the researching opportunities of the current paper: Firstly, this paper purely considers the bank loan financing for the capital-constrained manufacturer. In practice, the capital-constrained manufacturer may have several different financing resources, such as financing from an e-commerce platform or trade credit financing. Herein, it would be interesting to investigate other financing strategies in such a platform supply chain and compare the impacts of different financing resources on the supply chain performances. Secondly, this paper develops an e-commerce platform supply chain in which the manufacturer can choose either the agency mode or the reselling mode in an online marketplace. Recently, it poses an uptrend that the manufacturer can distribute its products simultaneously through both the online agency mode and the online reselling mode. A promising extension of this paper is to incorporate these two online channel modes simultaneously for a capital-constrained manufacturer in this platform supply chain. Thirdly, in practice, the government often provides some subsidies of the green investments to the manufacturer. Hence, it is valuable to investigate the optimal subsidy policy for the government. Lastly, this paper considers the demand of the green product to be deterministic. Another promising and challenging extension of this paper is to explore the case with a stochastic demand of the green product in such an e-commerce platform supply chain.
Acknowledgments
The authors would like to acknowledge the financial support from the National Social Science Fund of China (Grant number: 19BGL095), the Education Department of Shaanxi Provincial Government (Grant number: 19JK0355), and the Shaanxi Science and Technology Department (Grant number: 2020KRM001).
A. Proof of Proposition 1
With the reselling mode, the platform moves first and sets the markup
Clearly,
B. Proof of Corollary 1
(i) Based on Proposition 1, it always has
(ii)
(iii)
(iv)
Corollary 1 is thus completed.
C. Proof of Proposition 2
With the the agency mode, the manufacturer sets the retail price and the green effort simultaneously. Similarly, the Hessian matrix of
Clearly, the
Proposition 2 is thus completed.
D. Proof of Corollary 2
Based on Proposition 2, it always has
Proposition 2 is thus completed.
E. Proofs of Propositions 3 and 4
Based on Propositions 1 and 2, we have
Propositions 3 and 4 can thus be easily obtained.
[1] S. Huang, Z. P. Fan, N. Wang, "Green subsidy modes and pricing strategy in a capital-constrained supply chain," Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, vol. 136,DOI: 10.1016/j.tre.2020.101885, 2020.
[2] C. Liu, J. Chen, W. Cai, "Data-driven remanufacturability evaluation method of waste parts," IEEE Transactions on Industrial Informatics, vol. 18 no. 7, pp. 4587-4595, DOI: 10.1109/tii.2021.3118466, 2022.
[3] C. Y. Liu, H. Wang, J. Tang, C. T. Chang, Z. Liu, "Optimal recovery model in a used batteries closed-loop supply chain considering uncertain residual capacity," Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, vol. 156,DOI: 10.1016/j.tre.2021.102516, 2021b.
[4] R. S. Widrick, S. G. Nurre, M. J. Robbins, "Optimal policies for the management of an electric vehicle battery swap station," Transportation Science, vol. 52 no. 1, pp. 59-79, DOI: 10.1287/trsc.2016.0676, 2018.
[5] Reuters, "China’s central bank rolls out lending tool for carbon emission cuts," 2022. https://www.reuters.com/business/sustainable-business/china-central-bank-provide-low-cost-loans-carbon-emission-cuts-2021-11-08/
[6] L. Tian, A. J. Vakharia, Y. R. Tan, Y. Xu, "Marketplace, reseller, or hybrid: strategic analysis of an emerging e-commerce model," Production and Operations Management, vol. 27 no. 8, pp. 1595-1610, DOI: 10.1111/poms.12885, 2018.
[7] Z. Zhang, H. Xu, G. Y. Ke, K. Chen, "Selecting online distribution modes for differentiated products in a platform supply chain," International Journal of Production Economics, vol. 244,DOI: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2021.108384, 2022b.
[8] Y. J. Chen, J. B. Sheu, "Environmental-regulation pricing strategies for green supply chain management," Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, vol. 45 no. 5, pp. 667-677, DOI: 10.1016/j.tre.2009.04.010, 2009.
[9] S. R. Bhaskaran, V. Krishnan, "Effort, revenue, and cost sharing mechanisms for collaborative new product development," Management Science, vol. 55 no. 7, pp. 1152-1169, 2009.
[10] D. Ghosh, J. Shah, "A comparative analysis of greening policies across supply chain structures," International Journal of Production Economics, vol. 135 no. 2, pp. 568-583, DOI: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2011.05.027, 2012.
[11] B. Li, M. Zhu, Y. Jiang, Z. Li, "Pricing policies of a competitive dual-channel green supply chain," Journal of Cleaner Production, vol. 112, pp. 2029-2042, DOI: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2015.05.017, 2016.
[12] Q. Meng, M. Li, W. Liu, Z. Li, J. Zhang, "Pricing policies of dual-channel green supply chain: considering government subsidies and consumers’ dual preferences," Sustainable Production and Consumption, vol. 26, pp. 1021-1030, DOI: 10.1016/j.spc.2021.01.012, 2021.
[13] M. Das Roy, S. S. Sana, "Multi-echelon green supply chain model with random defectives, remanufacturing and rework under setup cost reduction and variable transportation cost," Sādhanā, vol. 46 no. 4, pp. 211-218, DOI: 10.1007/s12046-021-01716-y, 2021.
[14] Z. Liu, X. X. Zheng, D. F. Li, C. N. Liao, J. B. Sheu, "A novel cooperative game-based method to coordinate a sustainable supply chain under psychological uncertainty in fairness concerns," Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, vol. 147,DOI: 10.1016/j.tre.2021.102237, 2021c.
[15] S. S. Sana, "Price competition between green and non green products under corporate social responsible firm," Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services, vol. 55,DOI: 10.1016/j.jretconser.2020.102118, 2020.
[16] X. Chen, G. G. Cai, "Joint logistics and financial services by a 3pl firm," European Journal of Operational Research, vol. 214 no. 3, pp. 579-587, DOI: 10.1016/j.ejor.2011.05.010, 2011.
[17] G. Cai, X. Chen, Z. Xiao, "The roles of bank and trade credits: Theoretical analysis and empirical evidence," Production and Operations Management, vol. 23 no. 4, pp. 583-598, 2014.
[18] Z. C. Zhang, H. Y. Xu, K. B. Chen, "Operational decisions and financing strategies in a capital-constrained closed-loop supply chain," International Journal of Production Research, vol. 59 no. 15, pp. 4690-4710, DOI: 10.1080/00207543.2020.1770356, 2020b.
[19] X. Jin, H. Zhou, J. Wang, "Joint finance and order decision for supply chain with capital constraint of retailer considering product defect," Computers & Industrial Engineering, vol. 157,DOI: 10.1016/j.cie.2021.107293, 2021.
[20] N. Yan, Y. Zhang, X. Xu, Y. Gao, "Online finance with dual channels and bidirectional free-riding effect," International Journal of Production Economics, vol. 231,DOI: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2020.107834, 2021.
[21] Y. Zheng, Y. Zhao, N. Wang, X. Meng, H. Yang, "Financing decision for a remanufacturing supply chain with a capital constrained retailer: a study from the perspective of market uncertainty," International Journal of Production Economics, vol. 245,DOI: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2021.108397, 2022.
[22] S. S. Sana, J. Ferro-Correa, A. Quintero, R. Amaya, "A system dynamics model of financial flow in supply chains: a case study," RAIRO - Operations Research, vol. 52 no. 1, pp. 187-204, DOI: 10.1051/ro/2017025, 2018.
[23] N. Yan, X. He, Y. Liu, "Financing the capital-constrained supply chain with loss aversion: supplier finance vs. supplier investment," Omega, vol. 88, pp. 162-178, DOI: 10.1016/j.omega.2018.08.003, 2019.
[24] J. K. Ryan, D. Sun, X. Zhao, "Competition and coordination in online marketplaces," Production and Operations Management, vol. 21 no. 6, pp. 997-1014, DOI: 10.1111/j.1937-5956.2012.01332.x, 2012.
[25] T. M. Choi, L. Feng, R. Li, "Information disclosure structure in supply chains with rental service platforms in the blockchain technology era," International Journal of Production Economics, vol. 221,DOI: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2019.08.008, 2020.
[26] B. Jiang, K. Jerath, K. Srinivasan, "Firm strategies in the ”mid tail” of platform-based retailing," Marketing Science, vol. 30 no. 5, pp. 757-775, DOI: 10.1287/mksc.1110.0656, 2011.
[27] Q. Xu, Y. He, "Optimal information disclosure strategies for a retail platform in the blockchain technology era," International Journal of Production Research,DOI: 10.1080/00207543.2021.1976434, 2021.
[28] A. Hasani, S. H. Zegordi, E. Nikbakhsh, "Robust closed-loop global supply chain network design under uncertainty: the case of the medical device industry," International Journal of Production Research, vol. 53 no. 5, pp. 1596-1624, DOI: 10.1080/00207543.2014.965349, 2015.
[29] J. Wang, S. He, "Optimal decisions of modularity, prices and return policy in a dual-channel supply chain under mass customization," Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, vol. 160,DOI: 10.1016/j.tre.2022.102675, 2022.
[30] T. Zhang, T. M. Choi, "Optimal consumer sales tax policies for online-offline retail operations with consumer returns," Naval Research Logistics, vol. 68 no. 6, pp. 701-720, DOI: 10.1002/nav.21935, 2021.
[31] C. Dellarocas, "The Digitization of Word of Mouth: Promise and Challenges of online Feedback mechanisms," Management Science, vol. 49 no. 10, pp. 1407-1424, DOI: 10.1287/mnsc.49.10.1407.17308, 2003.
[32] Y. Deng, J. Zheng, W. Khern-am nuai, K. Kannan, "More than the quantity: the value of editorial reviews for a user-generated content platform," Management Science, vol. 68,DOI: 10.1287/mnsc.2021.4238, 2021.
[33] K. Kaushik, R. Mishra, N. P. Rana, Y. K. Dwivedi, "Exploring reviews and review sequences on e-commerce platform: a study of helpful reviews on Amazon.in," Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services, vol. 45, pp. 21-32, DOI: 10.1016/j.jretconser.2018.08.002, 2018.
[34] S. S. Sana, "Sale through dual channel retailing system—a mathematical approach," Sustainability Analytics and Modeling, vol. 2,DOI: 10.1016/j.samod.2022.100008, 2022.
[35] P. Zhang, Y. He, C. V. Shi, "Retailer’s channel structure choice: online channel, offline channel, or dual channels?," International Journal of Production Economics, vol. 191, pp. 37-50, DOI: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2017.05.013, 2017.
[36] X. Qin, Z. Liu, L. Tian, "The optimal combination between selling mode and logistics service strategy in an e-commerce market," European Journal of Operational Research, vol. 289 no. 2, pp. 639-651, DOI: 10.1016/j.ejor.2020.07.029, 2021.
[37] J. Sun, P. Yuan, L. Hua, "Pricing and financing strategies of a dual-channel supply chain with a capital-constrained manufacturer," Annals of Operations Research,DOI: 10.1007/s10479-022-04602-w, 2022.
[38] S. Zhang, J. Zhang, "Agency selling or reselling: E-tailer information sharing with supplier offline entry," European Journal of Operational Research, vol. 280 no. 1, pp. 134-151, DOI: 10.1016/j.ejor.2019.07.003, 2020.
[39] Z. Chen, Z. P. Fan, X. Zhao, "Offering return-freight insurance or not: strategic analysis of an e-seller’s decisions," Omega, vol. 103,DOI: 10.1016/j.omega.2021.102447, 2021.
[40] Y. Yu, X. Li, X. Xu, "Reselling or marketplace mode for an online platform: the choice between cap-and-trade and carbon tax regulation," Annals of Operations Research, vol. 310 no. 1, pp. 293-329, DOI: 10.1007/s10479-021-04250-6, 2022.
[41] Z. Zhang, H. Xu, K. Chen, Y. Zhao, Z. Liu, "Channel mode selection for an e-platform supply chain in the presence of a secondary marketplace," European Journal of Operational Research In press, vol. 305,DOI: 10.1016/j.ejor.2022.06.064, 2022a.
[42] Q. Wang, N. Zhao, X. Ji, "Reselling or agency selling? the strategic role of live streaming commerce in distribution contract selection," Electronic Commerce Research,DOI: 10.1007/s10660-022-09581-5, 2022.
[43] J. Wei, J. Lu, J. Zhao, "Interactions of competing manufacturers’ leader-follower relationship and sales format on online platforms," European Journal of Operational Research, vol. 280 no. 2, pp. 508-522, DOI: 10.1016/j.ejor.2019.07.048, 2020.
[44] J. Huang, M. Leng, M. Parlar, "Demand functions in decision modeling: a comprehensive survey and research directions," Decision Sciences, vol. 44 no. 3, pp. 557-609, DOI: 10.1111/deci.12021, 2013.
[45] W. Zhu, Y. He, "Green product design in supply chains under competition," European Journal of Operational Research, vol. 258 no. 1, pp. 165-180, DOI: 10.1016/j.ejor.2016.08.053, 2017.
[46] Jd, "Commissions and slotting fees announced publicly on jd.com," 2022. https://rule.jd.com/rule/ruleDetail.action?ruleId=638209647311982592&btype=1
[47] X. Geng, Y. R. Tan, L. Wei, "How add-on pricing interacts with distribution contracts," Production and Operations Management, vol. 27 no. 4, pp. 605-623, DOI: 10.1111/poms.12831, 2018.
[48] X. Guo, S. Zheng, Y. Yu, F. Zhang, "Optimal bundling strategy for a retail platform under agency selling," Production and Operations Management, vol. 30 no. 7, pp. 2273-2284, DOI: 10.1111/poms.13366, 2021.
[49] Z. Liu, K. W. Li, B. Y. Li, J. Huang, J. Tang, "Impact of product-design strategies on the operations of a closed-loop supply chain," Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, vol. 124, pp. 75-91, DOI: 10.1016/j.tre.2019.02.007, 2019.
[50] T. M. Choi, P. S. Chow, C. H. Lee, B. Shen, "Used intimate apparel collection programs: a game-theoretic analytical study," Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, vol. 109, pp. 44-62, DOI: 10.1016/j.tre.2017.10.017, 2018.
[51] Z. Liu, M. D. Wan, X. X. Zheng, S. L. Koh, "Fairness concerns and extended producer responsibility transmission in a circular supply chain," Industrial Marketing Management, vol. 102, pp. 216-228, DOI: 10.1016/j.indmarman.2022.01.014, 2022.
[52] P. Ma, J. Shang, H. Wang, "Enhancing corporate social responsibility: contract design under information asymmetry," Omega, vol. 67, pp. 19-30, DOI: 10.1016/j.omega.2016.03.004, 2017.
[53] Z. Zhang, H. Xu, Z. Liu, Y. Fang, "Implications for pure profit, environmental impact and social welfare in a socially responsible supply chain," Kybernetes, vol. 50, 2020a.
[54] Y. Kwark, J. Chen, S. Raghunathan, "Platform or wholesale? a strategic tool for online retailers to benefit from third-party information," MIS Quarterly, vol. 41 no. 3, pp. 763-785, DOI: 10.25300/misq/2017/41.3.05, 2017.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer
Copyright © 2023 Guobao Zhang et al. This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License (the “License”), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. Notwithstanding the ProQuest Terms and Conditions, you may use this content in accordance with the terms of the License. https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/
Abstract
This paper investigates operational decisions and online channel mode selection for green products with an e-commerce supply chain in which the manufacturer is subject to capital constraint. Starting from a Stackelberg game framework where the platform acts as a leader, two different online channel modes applied with an e-commerce supply chain are explored for equilibria, respectively. This paper then extends to a different supply chain with a reversed channel leadership, so as to reveal how the supply chain leaderships affect the equilibriums and supply chain performance. With the analytical studies, several important and interesting insights are derived. For example, but not limited to, the following is found: (a) the equilibrium decisions of the capital-constrained supply chain highly rely on the associated interest rate but are independent of the initial capital level of the financially-constrained manufacturer; (b) the platform and the capital-constrained manufacturer act largely differently when choosing the optimal online channel mode for themselves; (c) a win-win situation benefiting two parties holds when and only when the two members choose the agency mode under certain conditions; (d) the impacts of the supply chain leaderships and online channel modes on the consumer surplus and social welfare are clearly revealed. These results derived in our paper shed lights on industrial practicer on how to effectively make such decision-making in platform economy. The members in an e-commerce supply chain can appropriately determine their decisions such as commission and slotting fee to reach a win-win situation for two parties.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer