Introduction
In recent years, medical malpractice has frequently occurred in China. Examples include the following medical incidents: Hebei (2016), First Hospital of Peking University (2018), Anhui (2019), Civil Aviation General Hospital (2020) and the large-scale medical incident in the Huimin County People’s Hospital of Binzhou City (2017). China’s courts accepted approximately 59,777 medical malpractice cases from 2018 to 2021, with cases increasing annually. These statistics show that medical malpractice in China is increasing. These cases have a substantial negative impact on doctors’ reputation, patients’ trust, and harmony and stability of society. Patients, doctors, hospitals, and the government are dissatisfied with the current status of doctor–patient relationships, and measures must be adopted to manage them. It is important to analyze doctors’ and patients’ strategic choices in medical malpractice and establish a game model of the evolution of medical malpractice they engage in to build a harmonious doctor–patient relationship.
The concept of medical malpractice has not yet been uniformly defined in academia. The term, medical malpractice was first described in 2018 in the medical dispute prevention and handling ordinance in a government document. It was defined as a dispute between a doctor and patient arising from a medical and treatment activity [1]. In 1999, Meadows proposed an alternative dispute resolution tactic except traditional litigation [2]. In 2000, Sieg established a game model to identify trends and settlement strategies when faced with the uncertainty risk in medical malpractice [3]. Since 2000, scholars have started to focus on evolutionary game theory and have used it to study medical malpractice [4, 5]. The information asymmetry of medical malpractice satisfaction [6, 7], medical ethics [8], and other aspects was quantitatively analyzed and evaluated using game models [9] and evolutionary game models [10]. In addition, several mechanisms that may affect cooperative behavior. In 2019, Quan et al. In the stochastic evolution PGG model, the social exclusion mechanism is innovatively introduced. Based on corresponding simulation experiments in carried out in a structured population, the increasing-returns-to-scale effect can greatly reduce the critical values of the amplification factor under which cooperation can emerge [11]. In 2021, Tianyu Ren and Junjun Zheng introduce a tolerance-based expulsion mechanism into the spatial public goods game, reveal that tolerance-based expulsion can significantly foster cooperation and stabilize pure cooperation under negative conditions [12]. In 2022, Li et al. proposed an updating algorithm that show that if mobility is free, there is a window of parameters where synergies with network reciprocity are possible, and where cooperation can be robust and significantly elevated [13]. This paper establishes a 2 × 2 game model considering the doctor–patient relationship. However, there are far fewer doctors than patients. Generally, physician decisions may be influenced by different individuals whose relationships resemble small-world networks. In 2021, Jiang et al. explored contribute to the literature by exploring the role of group size in the collective risk social dilemma and the potential underlying mechanisms through model simulations and human experiments. This simulation results show that reducing the bystander effect by decreasing the group size can solve the collective-risk social dilemma [14]. Some studies have also found that social exclusion as a form of cooperation can significantly promote cooperation through additional cost [15]. Moreover, a fine-tuned interplay between the minority mobility and network reciprocity that are still functioning is most conducive to promoting cooperation, and the limited mobility of minorities could spare public resources in social dilemma situations more effectively than reward and punishment [16]. In recent years, scholars have begun to pay attention to the research of medical malpractice, using path analysis [17], game models [18], and literature reviews [19], and as well as using tolerance-based punishment and cooperation [20], pool expulsion and cooperation [21], prosocial and antisocial exclusion mechanisms [22] to analyze and evaluate factors affecting medical malpractice [23], medical practice income [24], and medical costs [25].
In summary, previous studies have focused on analyzing the game theory between doctors and patients and influencing cooperative behavior mechanisms, which helps reduce medical malpractice. However, few scholars have discussed how doctors’ choice of the combination of two strategies affect patients’ medical behavior. Few studies have used quantitative methods to explore the choice of two different combinations of strategies for physicians, patients’ medical behavior strategies, and how to control the factors affecting medical malpractice to evolve in the direction of established goals.
The main features of this research are as follows:
1. Based on the conditions of bounded rationality, medical malpractice can be interpreted as dynamic games of constant selection and mutation. The evolutionary game method was used to solve the problem of medical malpractice. Therefore, an evolutionary game model of doctors and patients was constructed. The research results present the balanced behavioral choices of doctors and patients, which align with the game situation between doctors and patients in medical malpractice.
2. The choice of stability strategies for doctors and patients in medical malpractice was studied by analyzing the equilibrium point and stability of the evolutionary game model between the players. Second, the model was simulated using Vensim by changing parameters, such as the doctor’s income and patient’s medical challenge. This reflects, intuitively, the evolutionary trend of doctors and patients in the medical malpractice process. Therefore, measures must be taken to alleviate the relationship between doctors and patients to ensure strong operability.
Methods
Basic assumptions and model building
Assume that there are two groups of doctors and patients, and one group is randomly selected from the group of doctors each time to match and play with the patients. Doctors and patients have limited rationality, they consider long-term cooperation and learn to constantly change their strategies until equilibrium is reached. The behavior of doctors is divided into: standardized practice and illegal practice, cooperation and conflict. The patient’s behavior is divided into non-medical malpractice and medical malpractice. Doctors’ standardized practices include complying with laws and regulations and ensuring the safety and quality of patients. Collaboration strategies include working with patients and enabling them to cooperate with treatments during the patient care process, ensuring effective communication and good treatment options. The patients’ non-medical behavior includes the behavior of choosing not to engage in medical disputes under the different strategies of the doctors.
In summary, there are two groups of participants in the evolutionary game model: doctors and patients. The doctors’ behaviors were grouped as: standardized practice, illegal practice, and cooperation and conflict. The patients’ behaviors were grouped into non-medical malpractice, and medical malpractice.
Hypothesis 1: The proportion of doctors practicing in a standardized manner is Y1 (0≤ Y1≤1), and in an irregular practice is 1-Y1. The proportion of doctors choosing cooperative strategy is Y2 (0≤ Y2≤1), and conflict strategy is 1-Y2. The proportion of patients who do not raise medical malpractice is X (0≤X≤1), and the proportion of patients with medical malpractice is 1-X.The probability of a doctor choosing an active strategy is Y; the weight of the doctor’s standardized practice and cooperative strategy on the doctor–patient relationship is expressed as S1 and S2, respectively.
Hypothesis 2: Some hospitals will engage in illegal practices to maximize benefits but do so at the patient’s expense. Such behaviors include unnecessary medical treatment for patients, prescribing overpriced drugs, and other improper means. These benefits are greater than those under the standardized practice state (recorded as PE2>PE1). Similarly, doctors choose different strategies in medical malpractice (cooperation or conflict), which will have different effects. In medical services, the cost a conflict between doctors and patients is higher than that of cooperation (denoted as O2> O1).
Hypothesis 3: Under Article 54 of the Tort Liability Law of the People’s Republic of China, a medical dispute occurs if a patient is damaged in the diagnosis and treatment activities of a medical dispute (this article is recorded as H). If the medical institution and its medical staff are at fault, the medical institution shall bear the liability for damages (this article is recorded as D). Concurrently, the government will oversee and penalize the doctor’s illegal practice under Article 47 of the Regulations on the Prevention and Handling of medical malpractice, which is recorded as M. When a medical malpractice case arises, some patients are dissatisfied with the compensation they receive. If the patient’s expected benefits are inconsistent through the normal channels of rights protection, additional compensation can be sought based on the “medical malpractice” strategy. In the medical malpractice process, the patient’s transportation expenses, lost work expenses, and other costs are recorded (this article is recorded as E).
Hypothesis 4: The patient’s “medical malpractice” behavior will instigate a decline in the doctor’s social reputation, potentially interfering with standard medical processes, and possibly precipitate other losses (this article is recorded as L1). For doctors practicing illegally, the patient’s “medical malpractice” will likely expose his/her illegal practice. The doctor’s behavior will be monitored by the government, media, social groups, and others. Therefore, the doctor will suffer greater losses (L2, L2>L1). Furthermore, the “medical malpractice” will not only disrupt the medical order but also negatively impact the harmony and stability of society, doctors’ social standing, and patients’ trust as the incident continues to deteriorate(K).
Based on the above assumptions, a doctor–patient evolutionary game benefit matrix was constructed, as shown in Table 1.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Evolutionary game analysis of doctors and patients
Equilibrium point of the evolutionary process
The expected benefits EA1 and EA2 of the physician’s selection of the normative practice and illegal practice, expected earnings EB1 and EB2 of the physician’s selection of the cooperation strategy and conflict strategy, and average expected return of the physician (EA)−, (EB)− are expressed as:(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
According to the Malthusian dynamic equation, the growth rate of the number of physician’s normative practice strategies is equal to EA1 minus the average return, the growth rate of the number of physician cooperative strategies is equal to EB1 minus the average return, and T is the time, which solves the doctor’s replication dynamic equation:
Let Y represent the probability of the doctor choosing the active strategy, and S1 and S2 represent the weight of the doctor–patient relationship of the standardized practice and cooperation strategy of the doctor, respectively.
(7)(8)(9)
From this, the replicating dynamic equation for the positive strategy of the medical prescription can be obtained as follows:(10)(11)
Similarly, the expected benefits of EC1 and EC2 and the average benefits of patients choosing a non-medical strategy are:(12)(13)(14)
The replication dynamic equations for patients are:(15)
From the above two equations, a two-dimensional power system (L) can be obtained.
(16)
To facilitate the analysis of the equilibrium point and stability of the system, we formulate(17)
Proposition 1: The equilibrium point of the system is A(0,0) B(0,Y*)C(1,0)D(1,Y*)
Proof: For a two-dimensional dynamical system (L), with dY/dtT = 0 and dX/dT = 0, (0,0), (0, Y*), (1,0), (1, Y*) are the equilibrium points of the system. Including (0, Y*) and (1, Y*) into the system (L) can also make dY/dT = 0 and dX/dT = 0, that is, four equilibrium points of the system (L) are obtained.
Equilibrium point and stability analysis
The stability of the evolutionary equilibrium point can be derived from the local Jacobi stability analysis of dynamical systems [26]. Thus, the stable state of the equilibrium point is determined by calculating the eigenvalues of the Jacobi matrix.
(18A)(18B)
Where A11, A12, A21 and A22 expressed as follows:(19)(20)(21)(22)
If both of the following conditions are met, the equilibrium point of the duplication dynamic equation is the evolutionary stabilization strategy (ESS).
(23)(24)
Therefore, four local equilibrium points can be obtained, i.e., A11, A12, A21 and A22 (as shown in Table 2 below).
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
(25)
According to the determinant values and trace of the Jacobi matrix, the values of the determinant and trace of the Jacobi matrix J at each equilibrium point can be obtained, and the local stability can be judged.
1. When E<D and S2(O2-O1)/2S1+ KL1-KL2-M <PE2-PE1<0 or E<D and PE2-PE1>0, the evolutionary stability strategy (ESS) of the system is (0,0).
2. The ESS of the system is (0, y*) when E>D and PE2-PE1<S2(O2-O1)/2S1+ KL1-KL2-M, or E<D and PE2-PE1<S2(O2-O1)/2S1+ KL1-KL2-M.
3. When E>D and S2(O2-O1)/S21+ KL1-KL2-M <PE2-PE1<0, or when E>D and PE2-PE1< S2(O2-O1)/2S1+ KL1-KL2-M, the ESS of the system is (1, y*).
4. When E>D and 0<PE2-PE1<S2(O2-O1)/2S1+ KL1-KL2-M, or when E>D and PE2-PE1<S2(O2-O1)/2S1+ KL1-KL2-M, the ESS of the system is (1,0).
Based on the two-dimensional dynamic system in the text, the local stability of the Jacobi matrix J can be judged according to the values of each equilibrium point and determinant of the Jacobi matrix. Therefore, according to the values of the determinant and trace of the Jacobian matrix, the first and second cases are shown in Tables 3 and 4, respectively. The evolutionary stability judgment method of the other cases is consistent and will not be described in detail.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Results and discussion
Evolutionary game model based on system dynamics
The following uses the system dynamics simulation software Vensim PLE to simulate changes in physician and patient strategies. According to the parameters of each game subject and the relationship between parameters, the evolutionary game theory model of doctors and patients is established, (Fig 1).
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Evolutionary simulation research
Suppose K = 0.4, S1 = 0.5, S2 = 0.5, PE1 = 0.5, PE2 = 0.8, O1 = 0.2, O2 = 0.4, H = 0.6, D = 0.6, M = 0.9, E = 0.3, L1 = 0.1, and L2 = 0.3. On this basis, the income (PE1) when doctors regulate their practice is adjusted to observe the change in the probability (Y) of doctors regulating practice with their income (PE1). The simulation results of PE1 of current, current 1 and current 2 were 0.4, 0.6 and 0.8, respectively, as shown in Figs 2 and 3. The higher the income obtained by the doctor’s standardized practice, the higher the probability of choosing to practice in a standardized manner. When the standardized practicing doctor’s income is greater than or equal to that of the illegal practice, the probability of the doctor choosing the standardized practice increases. This shows that effectively controlling and regulating the benefits of standardized practices is conducive to encouraging doctors to provide standardized (legal) strategies as soon as possible.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
(current: PE1 = 0.4; current 1; PE1 = 0.6 and current 2:PE1 = 0.8).
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
(current: PE1 = 0.4; current 1; PE1 = 0.6 and current 2:PE1 = 0.8).
The adjusted weights of doctors’ standardized practices after choosing cooperation strategies vary in different cases are as follows: current: S1 = 0.1, S2 = 0.8; current 1: S1 = 0.2, S2 = 0.7and current 2: S1 = 0.3, S2 = 0.6. As shown in Figs 4 and 5, as the doctor’s standardized practice weight S1 declines and the weight of selecting a cooperative strategy S2 increases, the probability of choosing a negative strategy increases. This result indicates that the standardized practice strategy has a high proportion when doctors choose an active strategy. Therefore, by increasing the income of standardized practices between doctors, it is more effective to promote the choice of active strategies by doctors. However, as shown in Fig 4, the changes in S1 and S2 values do not fluctuate much on the patients’ medical malpractice behavior curve.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
(current: S1 = 0.1, S2 = 0.8; current 1: S1 = 0.2, S2 = 0.7and current 2:S1 = 0.3, S2 = 0.6).
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
(current: S1 = 0.1, S2 = 0.8; current 1: S1 = 0.2, S2 = 0.7and current 2:S1 = 0.3, S2 = 0.6).
By adjusting the patient’s medical alarm cost, the following results were obtained: current: E = 0.3, PE1 = 0.5; current 1: E = 0.4, PE1 = 0.5 and PE1 when current 2: E = 0.4, PE1 = 0.6, improving physician practice. In the case of increasing E at the same time, increasing PE1 can improve physicians’ proactive strategies. In this case, controlling the benefits of PE1 from the standardized practice of physicians can more effectively increase the probability of patients not filing medical malpractice cases than controlling the cost of medical confusion for patients. As shown in Figs 6 and 7, when the income of doctors to standardize practice (PE1) is between 0.6 and 0.8, patients are more effective in reducing medical malpractice behavior.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
(current: E = 0.3, PE1 = 0.5; current 1: E = 0.4, PE1 = 0.5; current 2: E = 0.4, PE1 = 0.6).
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Conclusion
The evolutionary game method is applied to medical malpractice under information asymmetry and limited rationality conditions. The evolutionary game model of doctors and patients was thus established, and a simulation analysis was conducted by determining their respective replication dynamic equations and evolutionary stability strategies. We concluded that the weight of doctors’ standardized practice and cooperation strategies, benefits of doctors’ standardized practice, and patients’ medical noise costs are the key factors affecting the players’ evolutionary game behaviors. Based on the above research conclusions, the measures proposed to resolve medical malpractice from the doctors’ perspective have strong relevance, and the following actions are necessary:
First, third-party supervision and management systems should be improved. In medical malpractice, social media adheres to the principle of objective and fair reporting to assist government management departments in overseeing offending doctors. The government formulates methods and systems for recognizing doctors and patients and raises the threshold for violations. This is done by comparing the situation involving the doctors’ instruments and equipment, staffing, quality, ability, and capital investment. Ensuring that doctors and patients receive the appropriate levels of respect and service, parallel to government-assessed hospital management, will help standardize conducting doctors’ duties.
Second, a doctor–patient information management system should be established. Currently, there is no separate medical malpractice data on the Chinese Central Government’s Official Web Portal. Therefore, to realize the real-time control of medical malpractice by the government and public, a network information platform should be used to build a medical dispute management information system. This platform can enable the timely publication of medical malpractice cases as they occur, effectively manage the medical malpractice database, and reduce government supervision and penalization costs.
Third, doctors’ reward and punishment mechanisms should be improved. Model studies have shown that when a doctor’s gain is substantial, they conduct their duties although the patient is uncooperative. Therefore, a clear penalization system should be established for non-compliant doctors, reducing their number of patients and payment of substantial fines. At the same time, an incentive system should be established for doctors. Bonuses, welfare subsidies, and public awards could be provided to doctors who conscientiously conduct their duties, increasing their trust and credibility over their lifetime and work enthusiasm. The evolutionary game model of doctors and patients established in this study explored the strategy selection problems of two strategies in the process of medical malpractice. The game theory between doctors and patients in medical malpractice also needs to consider government regulations and medical insurance policy, that is, the strategic choice of multi-party stakeholders such as pharmaceutical companies. Thus, it is impossible to analyze various situations in a model. At the same time, this study did not consider that there are plenty of mechanisms that may affect cooperative behaviors, such as network reciprocity, and expulsion. Our next step will be to incorporate it into the model to discuss its impact on medical malpractice. This study provides a basis for further research direction to explore the problem of effective management of medical malpractice by multiple parties.
Supporting information
S1 Video. The effect of PE1 on physician positive strategy and standard medical practice strategy selection in evolutionary game theory model of doctors and patients in medical malpractice.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0282434.s001
(MOV)
S2 Video. Effects of S1 and S2 on physicians’ positive and patients’ strategy selection.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0282434.s002
(MOV)
S3 Video. Effects of E and PE1 on the choice of active medical strategies for physicians and non-medical malpractice strategy for patients.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0282434.s003
(MOV)
S1 Data.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0282434.s004
(ZIP)
Acknowledgments
We thank the participants of the study.
Citation: Song L, Yu Z, He Q (2023) Evolutionary game theory and simulations based on doctor and patient medical malpractice. PLoS ONE 18(3): e0282434. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0282434
About the Authors:
Lin Song
Roles: Conceptualization, Data curation, Formal analysis, Investigation, Methodology, Project administration, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing
Affiliation: Tianjin University of Traditional Chinese Medicine, Tianjin, China
ORICD: https://orcid.org/0000-0001-5568-8090
Zhenlei Yu
Roles: Investigation, Methodology, Project administration, Writing – original draft
Affiliation: Information Ministry of Library, Qilu University of Technology, Jinan, China
ORICD: https://orcid.org/0000-0002-4354-2972
Qiang He
Roles: Conceptualization, Funding acquisition, Investigation, Methodology, Project administration, Supervision, Writing – review & editing
E-mail: [email protected]
Affiliation: Tianjin University of Traditional Chinese Medicine, Tianjin, China
ORICD: https://orcid.org/0000-0002-8229-5476
1. No. 701 of the State Council of the People’s Republic of China. Available online: http://www.gov.cn/zhengce/content/2018-08/31/content_5318057.htm (accessed on 31 August (2018).
2. Meadows K K. Resolving Medical Malpractice Disputes in Massachusetts: Statutory and Judicial Initia tives in Alternative Dispute Resolution. Suffolk J. Trial & App. Advoc.1999;4: 165.
3. Sieg H. Estimating a bargaining model with asymmetric information: Evidence from medical malpractice disputes. Journal of Political Economy. 2000,;108(5): 1006–1021.doi.org/10.1086/317677
4. Colman A M. Beyond rationality: Rigor without mortis in game theory. Behavioral and Brain Sciences. 2003; 26(2): 180–198.
5. Tarrant C C. Continuity, trust and cooperation: a game theory perspective on the GP-patient interaction. Ph.D. Thesis, University of Leicester, Leicester, England,2006.
6. Schneider U, Ulrich V.The physician-patient relationship revisited—The patient’s view. International Journal of Health Economics and Management. 2008; 8(4):279–300. pmid:18597172
7. Liang C, Gu D, Tao F, Jain Hemant K, Yu Zhao, Bin Ding. Influence of mechanism of patient-accessible hospital information system implementation on doctor–patient relationships: A service fairness perspective. Information &Management. 2017;54(1):57–72.
8. Aziz V M. Cultural aspects of the patient-doctor relationship. International Psychogeriatrics. 2009; 21(2):415–417. pmid:19040785
9. Tarrant C, Dixon-Woods M, Colman A M, Tim S. Continuity and trust in primary care: a qualitative study informed by game theory. The Annals of Family Medicine.2010; 8(5): 440–446. pmid:20843886
10. Deng X, Han D, Dezert J, Yong D, Yu S. Evidence combination from an evolutionary game theory perspective. IEEE transactions on cybernetics. 2015; 46(9): 2070–2082. pmid:26285231
11. Quan J, Zheng J, Wang X, Yang X. The effect of increasing returns to scale in public goods investment on threshold values of cooperation under social exclusion mechanism. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications. 2019; 532: 121866.doi.org/10.1016/j.physa.2019.121866
12. Ren T, Zheng J. Evolutionary dynamics in the spatial public goods game with tolerance-based expulsion and cooperation. Chaos, Solitons & Fractals. 2021; 151: 111241.
13. Li W J, Chen Z, Jin Z, Wang J, Yuan L, Gu C, et al. Options for mobility and network reciprocity to jointly yield robust cooperation in social dilemmas. Applied Mathematics and Computation. 2022; 435: 127456.
14. Jiang L L, Gao J, Chen Z, Li W J, Jürgen K. Reducing the bystander effect via decreasing group size to solve the collective-risk social dilemma. Applied Mathematics and Computation. 2021; 410: 126445.
15. Zhou K, Ren T. Low-carbon technology collaborative innovation in industrial cluster with social exclusion: an evolutionary game theory perspective. Chaos: An Interdisciplinary Journal of Nonlinear Science. 2021; 31(3): 033124. https://doi.org/10.1063/5.0037956
16. Li W J, Jiang L L, Perc M. A limited mobility of minorities facilitates cooperation in social dilemmas. Applied Mathematics and Computation. 2021; 391: 125705.doi.org/10.1016/j.amc.2020.125705
17. Zheng H, Jiang S, Wu Q. Factors influencing COVID-19 vaccination intention: The roles of vaccine knowledge, vaccine risk perception, and doctor–patient communication. Patient Education and Counseling. 2022; 105(2): 277–283. pmid:34565643
18. Liu J, Yu C, Li C, Han J. Cooperation or conflict in doctor–patient relationship? An analysis from the perspective of evolutionary game. IEEE Access. 2020; 8: 42898–42908.
19. Ward P. Trust and communication in a doctor–patient relationship: a literature review. Arch Med. 2018; 3(3):36.
20. Zhang S, Zhang Z, Wu Y, Yan M, Xie Y. Tolerance-based punishment and cooperation in spatial public goods game. Chaos, Solitons & Fractals. 2018; 110: 267–272.
21. Wang X, Duh M, Perc M. Pool expulsion and cooperation in the spatial public goods game. Physics Letters A. 2020; 384(18):126391.
22. Liu L, Chen X. Evolutionary game dynamics in multiagent systems with prosocial and antisocial exclusion strategies. Knowledge-Based Systems. 2020; 188: 104835.
23. Chipidza F E, Wallwork R S, Stern T A. Impact of the doctor–patient relationship. The primary care companion for CNS disorders. 2015; 17(5). pmid:26835164
24. Zeng Y, Zhang L, Yao G, Fang Y. Analysis of current situation and influencing factor of medical disputes among different levels of medical institutions based on the game theory in Xiamen of China: A cross-sectional survey. Medicine. 2018; 97(38). pmid:30235759
25. Reschovsky J D, Saiontz‐Martinez C B. Malpractice claim fears and the costs of treating medicare patients: a new approach to estimating the costs of defensive medicine. Health services research. 2018; 53(3):1498–1516. pmid:28127752
26. Friedman D. Evolutionary games in economics. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society. 1991; 637–666.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer
© 2023 Song et al. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License: http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ (the “License”), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited. Notwithstanding the ProQuest Terms and Conditions, you may use this content in accordance with the terms of the License.
Abstract
Doctors and patients are the two critical players in medical malpractice. The evolutionary game model of doctors and patients is constructed based on information asymmetry and bounded rationality. The strategy selection problem of the two players in the medical malpractice process was studied. With change in different parameters, the evolutionary equilibrium strategy of the model was demonstrated using Vensim simulation. The results show that the weight, penalty amount, benefits of standardized practices, and patient medical alarm cost of strategies of different doctors are the key factors affecting doctor–patient evolutionary game system. Medical malpractice can be reduced by adjusting the weight of different strategy choices, increasing the penalties for illegal practices, and standardizing medical malpractice costs based on doctors’ standardized practice income. Measures to effectively resolve medical malpractice are proposed by introducing a third-party normative system, establishing a doctor–patient information management system, and improving doctors’ reward and punishment mechanisms.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer