1. Introduction
The advancement and utilization of life sciences and biotechnology have significantly transformed humanity’s comprehension of life essence, overhauled the prevention, diagnosis, and management of illnesses, and delivered unparalleled advancements in enhancing human health and well-being. In the context of China’s 14th Five-Year Plan, the biopharmaceutical industry has placed a high priority on the exploration and development of innovative medications, leading to an average annual growth rate of over 20% in research and development (R&D) investment across the sector. As a result, the number of new drugs under research and development has risen to the second position globally [1]. However, the current healthcare system in China is not adequately meeting the medical needs of the population, which presents a challenge for the country in terms of advancing biopharmaceutical innovation. The "2023 China Biopharmaceutical Industry Report" from the China Machinery Industry Information Research Institute revealed that only 9% of the domestic pharmaceutical market in China consists of innovative drugs, while other G20 countries have more than 20% of their markets dedicated to innovative drugs. Additionally, developed countries such as the United States, Japan, and Germany have over 50% of their pharmaceutical markets focused on innovative drugs [2]. This disparity in the production of high-end versus low-end drugs is impeding the realization of the "Healthy China" goal. Considering the situation in China, there is a need for comprehensive strategies to drive innovation in biomedical technology.
The knowledge spillover effect offers potential for improvements in technology across numerous developing nations during the early phases of drug innovation. These countries can avoid paying to invest in costly novel molecular entities but instead make quick technological development by imitating pharmacological therapy. Similar to other developing nations, China’s nascent pharmaceutical industry lacked the prerequisites for advanced pharmaceutical innovation due to its delayed inception, limited capital, inadequate accumulation of equipment and technology, unregulated market, and imperfect legal framework, leading it to adopt the strategy of imitating drug therapies to circumvent these challenges. Since the 1980s, domestic Chinese pharmaceutical firms have actively acquired foreign technologies and commenced the production of generic drugs [3]. As of 2021, the proportion of generic drugs in China is still as high as 63% [4]. (More detailed information regarding China’s biopharmaceutical industry development can be found in the online supplemental material). In the current phase of development, China’s pharmaceutical innovation advancement cannot rely solely on imitating drug therapies. Instead, it is necessary to reconsider the significance of knowledge spillover effects in achieving this upgrade.
The analysis of knowledge spillovers carries substantial economic and social implications and has attracted considerable attention from economists. Early studies concentrated on exploring the transfer effect, learning effect, and imitation effect associated with spillovers, and investigated the impact on productivity and creativity, leading to a significant amount of empirical evidence. The research had shown that knowledge spillovers have a substantial positive effect on the productivity and innovation persistence of German firms [5, 6], the productivity of the U.S. wartime shipbuilding industry [7], the creativity of India’s pharmaceutical manufacturing industry [8], and the knowledge acquisition capacity of start-ups [9]. Moreover, studies investigated the learning-by-hire effect (in the U.S. pharmaceutical industry) [10], the U.S. Patent Innovation Network [11], the Global Open-Source Software Project [12], and worldwide R&D mobility [13]. Their studies had verified the beneficial impact of knowledge spillover. Additionally, knowledge spillovers are recognized as a significant driver of economic growth in endogenous economic growth theory [14–16].
However, there is an increasing amount of evidence suggesting that spillover effects may not adhere to the idealized assumptions that were previously held, partly because competitive influences have been overlooked. Knowledge externalities refer to a range of factors, including the Marshall-Arrow-Romer (MAR) externality [17–19], the Jacobs externality [20], and the Porter externality [21], each of which has distinct impacts. When considering spillovers within competitive markets, they can lead to unforeseen conclusions. In academic settings, knowledge spillovers and competition effects may counteract each other, leading to a decline in academic output due to the law of diminishing marginal benefits [22]. Similar effects are observed in firm competition, where fierce competition discourages firms from innovating and results in an inverted U-shape relationship between spillovers and firm innovation [23, 24]. The positive effects of spillovers are limited by the fact that a large technological gap makes it difficult for laggards to absorb knowledge [25]. This article also investigates the spillover effects in competitive markets. Given that fierce competition can potentially distort the direction of R&D activities conducted by pharmaceutical companies [26], it is necessary to reassess the relevance of findings from previous research to the pharmaceutical market.
In addition, the complexity of spillover effects becomes more pronounced when the potential to respond to external knowledge is taken into account. Technology spillovers can occur naturally or be deliberately controlled, indicating that firms consider the influence of spillovers in their R&D decisions and strive to respond to knowledge externalities. The model of endogenous technological spillovers proposes that firms can respond to spillovers and enhance the benefits while minimizing the drawbacks by managing the turnover of R&D personnel [27]. The endogenous nature of spillovers is also evident in R&D collaboration between firms [28] and in firms’ patent transfer behavior in technology exchanges [29, 30]. However, it is regrettable that most of these studies are based on theoretical modeling explorations, necessitating the search for more empirical evidence.
Based on prior research, our investigation thoroughly explores the analysis of spillover effects, taking into account the impact of market competition and firms’ decisions to internalize spillovers. Specifically, we extend the foundational framework proposed by Bloom et al. [31], focusing on the characteristics of Chinese pharmaceutical firms. Our analysis centers on an R&D game involving N vertically integrated pharmaceutical firms, wherein firms initially decide on investments in the upstream R&D market before engaging in competition within the downstream product market. Throughout the game, pharmaceutical firms must consider the R&D investments and patenting activities of their rivals, utilizing patents to restrict knowledge spillovers. Ultimately, the equilibrium of a firm’s R&D investment hinges on the strategic substitution and strategic complementarity nature of the investment. To validate the practical applicability of these theoretical analyses, we compile a new dataset encompassing the financial information of Chinese A-share pharmaceutical listed companies and detailed patent application data, enabling a more precise assessment of endogenous knowledge spillovers.
This study presents interesting findings. Contrary to expectations, the research suggests that these spillovers may impede rather than enhance pharmaceutical innovation. This phenomenon occurs as a result of an abundance of pharmaceutical companies located in a single R&D area. It leads to a strategic substitution of investments in R&D among these companies, while operating within the limitations of the patent race paradigm. The empirical evidence supports these conclusions. The study recommends policy interventions such as "loser’s subsidies", reallocation of R&D resources, and adjustments to competition policies to encourage pharmaceutical firms to actively participate in R&D endeavors for the betterment of public health.
The potential contributions of this paper are as follows: Our study offers insights on the direction of technical advancement in emerging economies. In comparison to developed nations, the innovation system and policy environment in developing countries require enhancement, and spillovers do not operate within a perfect market mechanism. We examine the impact of spillovers using China, the world’s largest developing country, and propose potential routes to achieve high-quality innovation. Secondly, our study concentrates on endogenous knowledge spillovers and encompasses the competitive externalities of knowledge. This leads to distinctive findings and enhances the understanding of the relationship between spillovers and firm innovation. Notably, we find evidence that spillovers hinder innovative activity, aligning with existing theories of an inverted U-shaped relationship, particularly in the latter half of the curve. Thirdly, We created a novel dataset by acquiring comprehensive patent application information from Chinese biopharmaceutical companies through the PatSnap database. This data was then combined with existing financial data using precise field matching and fuzzy matching algorithms. This enables us to expand upon existing measures and investigate the impact of endogenous knowledge spillovers in greater depth.
The organization of this article is outlined as follows: Section 2 presents the analytical framework. Section 3 describes the data. Section 4 consists of empirical analysis, including validation of underlying assumptions, regression of benchmark models, robustness checks, mechanism analysis and heterogeneity. Section 5 outlines the policy implications. Section 6 summarizes and discusses the research findings.
2. Analytical framework
In this section, we initially examine a natural knowledge spillover scenario, where firms perceive knowledge spillovers as external factors and respond reactively to changes in external knowledge flows in their decision-making process. This natural knowledge spillover scenario serves as the fundamental framework for our subsequent analysis. Following this, we examine a knowledge protection scenario that is endogenously determined, in which the firm no longer perceives external knowledge as an exogenous variable. Instead, it exercises control over its interactions with external knowledge by engaging in patent filing.
2.1 Game settings
In both models, the game involves N firms, all of which are vertically integrated. The majority of Chinese pharmaceutical firms have adopted a vertically integrated organizational structure, a trend attributed by domestic Chinese scholars to the deficiencies in the Chinese market system. The high transaction costs associated with external transactions have led firms to internalize these costs, thus favoring vertical integration. Additionally, our model differs subtly from Bloom et al. [31] in that we incorporate the competitive impacts of knowledge spillovers without explicitly distinguishing between naturally occurring technological spillovers and those resulting from product competition. We argue that spillovers should include both forms, and our main concern is the final influence of spillovers on firms’ innovation endeavors.
In the game, all firms are arranged to engage in competition within both the upstream research and development (R&D) market and the downstream product market. Given that all firms are vertically integrated, the R&D decision-making process of each firm must take into account the goal of maximizing profits in the product market. Particularly, in the first stage, firms engage in R&D investment, with knowledge spillovers occurring between them. This implies that the R&D choices of a firm are influenced by the R&D decisions of its competitor firms. In the second stage, the firm competes in the downstream product market, which may involve quantity or price competition, without specifying the form of competition. It is crucial to acknowledge that increased investment in R&D can provide companies with a competitive advantage in product development, but it also entails additional expenses. Consequently, firms’ decisions in both R&D and product markets are interconnected, requiring them to consider how to maximize product market revenues when making R&D investments. In game modeling, we determine the game equilibrium using backward induction.
2.2 Natural knowledge spillover
First, let us analyze the competition in the product market (the second stage of the game). πi = π(ri,r−i) is profit function for firm i, where ri is the R&D investment of firm i. r−i has a dual implication, as it refers to both the knowledge acquisition resulting from the natural transfer of technology and the strategic actions adopted by a corporation in reaction to the R&D activities of its rivals. Generally, πi is increasing in ri and concave but uncertain about r−i, i.e., , . Note that firm i’s own R&D and other firms R&D are strategic substitutes if and strategic complements if . In order to maximize profits in a competitive product market, the optimal response function for firm i is given by , could be the optimal output or price depends on whether firms compete on quantity or price. Solving for second stage Nash decisions yields , we use to represent the equilibrium of competition in the product market. For example, firms compete on quantity and P is the exogenous market price that firms are facing. Thus, the quantity x and the average cost c are the function of ri and r−i, i.e., x(ri,r−i) or c(ri,r−i) [32]. If the firm profit in product market expresses as Πi = x(P−c), thus Πi is the function of ri and r−i, i.e., Πi(ri,r−i).
After that, firm i selects optimal R&D expenditure to maximize net value Vi under unconstrained conditions:(1)
And the first order condition (FOC) is,(2)
where . Similarly, , . And by the second order condition. Differentiating the formula:(3)subsequently, we obtain:(4)
The Eq (4) says that how r−i affects depends on , because firms profit function is concave and thus . When ri and r−i are strategic substitutes, means and make the . When firms R&D are strategic complements is similar, means and make . It is straightforward to demonstrate that these conditions are applicable in the scenario involving the participation of N firms. In this fundamental game model, firms consider external knowledge as an exogenous factor and merely react passively to external knowledge. While the fundamental model may not entirely capture the complexity of firms’ R&D behavior, the equations offer a theoretical framework for comprehending firms’ R&D decisions.
2.3 Endogenous knowledge protection decisions
In a competitive market, companies consider the impact of knowledge spillovers on their R&D decision-making processes and employ various mechanisms to safeguard knowledge in order to capitalize on the economic benefits of technological innovations over an extended period. This illustrates the endogenous character of knowledge spillovers, indicating that organizations engage in knowledge management to protect their intellectual capital [27]. Enterprises employ various methods to safeguard their knowledge, such as intellectual property rights and technology secrecy, as suggested by Klein [33]. In the game, the patent application is depicted as the sole method for safeguarding knowledge. This study examines the decision-making process of firms in protecting their knowledge as an endogenous variable in their R&D decisions. Specifically, we expand upon the fundamental model and analyze a two-stage game.
In the first stage, firm i choose R&D investment ri and the proportion of patent applications (or intensity of knowledge protection) ρi∈[0,1]. Let γ∈[1,+∞) be the exogenous parameter represent the effectiveness of firms’ patent application behavior, its size depends on the quality of the intellectual property system in a given country or region and the characteristics of the industry’s knowledge production (e.g. R&D barriers). Thus, the rents that firm i can receive from technological innovations are δiki = ki(ρiγ+1−ρi), ki = ki(ri,r−i). ki is increasing in both ri and r−i imply that and . At the same time, patent application is not free of charge and incurs corresponding unit costs g, and the total cost of firm i’s patent application behavior is gρiki.
In the second stage, firms compete in product markets, similar to the previous basic model, the optimal response function for firm i is given by . In this function, could be the optimal output or price. The second stage Nash decisions yields , where Ki = δiki is firm i’s knowledge stock and K−i = δ−ik−i is other firms’ knowledge stock. And Πi(Ki,K−i) is the equilibrium of competition in the product market. Note that Πi is increasing in Ki and concave but decreasing in K−i, imply that , <0 and . Based on the Nash equilibrium in the product market, we can solve for the optimal R&D investment and the optimal level of knowledge protection . Specifically, firms make R&D decisions by maximizing Eq (5):(5)
The first order conditions (FOC) are:(6)(7)where , . Similarly, , , , . According to the FOC, we can obtain , . The total differential equations are obtained through the FOC:(8)
In this paper, we focus on how R&D investment by other firms affects the R&D behavior of the focal firm i. By comparative static analysis based on multiple choice variables, we obtain:(9)(10)(11)(12)
When we observe the effect of r−i on , we assume that the change in dρ−i is tiny. For the same reason, we assume dr−i is tiny in a later study. In the above equation, , , , . is the hessian matrix. And , because of concave net value function Vi, for the same reason. This means Πi is a diminishing marginal return on Ki. Note that the sign of and is ambiguous. because more R&D leads to more knowledge protection. Based on the above analysis, it can be seen:(13)
Similarly, we have:(14)
And for the impact of ρ−i on or ,(15)(16)
Similarly, we can obtain:(17)
In the above equation, . Thus,(18)
These formulations suggest that the effect of spillovers on firms’ R&D behavior is contingent upon specific theoretical scenarios and assumptions. It is therefore logical to differentiate between the sign of and , specifically to examine two potential scenarios—strategic substitution ( and less than 0) or complementary ( and greater than 0) of R&D endeavors among enterprises.
Firstly, in the case where R&D endeavors among firms act as strategic substitutes, the R&D expenditures and patent application activities of competitors will diminish the optimal R&D investment and the inclination to seek patents for the firm (see Eq (13) to Eq (16)). This implies that the occurrence of spillovers in this situation will adversely affect the innovation activities of firms. The concept of strategic substitutes in investment can be elucidated by considering these analyses within the framework of a patent race. According to Loury’s patent race model [34], the initial firm that invests in R&D and obtain a patent will possess a distinct competitive edge. This edge is achieved by preventing rivals from acquiring comparable technology. Consequently, subsequent researchers may invest less in R&D, thereby reducing the probability of obtaining relevant patents, which leading to negative spillover effects [35].
Furthermore, the scenario becomes increasingly intricate when firms’ R&D endeavors exhibit strategic complementarity (also see Eq (13) and Eq (14)). This is attributed to our inability to ascertain the positive or negative nature of . The strategic complementary of R&D investments between enterprises stems from the fact that organizations operating in the same technology field follow distinct R&D methods, enabling mutual learning among them [36]. Moreover, the technologies utilized vary to a certain degree, leading to research and development companies manufacturing items that are distinctive. As a result, these firms are able to establish separate market fields. This implies that there is a lack of severe competition between enterprises, or that the impact of business stealing effect is not considerable. In this scenario, the beneficial impacts of natural knowledge spillover prevail, and these effects generally have favorable benefits. The presence of strategic complementary in R&D among enterprises is a widespread phenomenon that presents a challenge for future empirical research.
Ultimately, the findings indicate that the strategic substitutions or complementarity of knowledge stock between firms will have an impact on the knowledge stock of the firm i (see Eq (18)). This is akin to the examination of R&D expenditures mentioned earlier.
Within the theoretical framework, we establish fundamental assumptions and differentiate between two potential scenarios. Next, we need to decide if R&D endeavors made by biopharmaceutical companies in China are strategic substitutes or strategic complements.
2.4 R&D activities in chinese biopharmaceuticals
Considering the fundamental facts and underlying reasons presented in the subsequent paragraphs, it is highly probable that R&D operations among Chinese pharmaceutical firms are strategic substitutes rather than strategic complements.
Firstly, the scenarios outlined in the patent model [34] closely resemble the R&D practices of biopharmaceutical companies. Owing to reduced R&D expenses associated with generic drugs, manufacturers of generic medications possess a competitive cost advantage. With an increasing number of companies entering the market to produce similar drugs, these entities are likely to provide greater discounts to consumers, resulting in a decline in overall market prices. This leads to significant profit losses for the original drug manufacturers, creating challenges in recovering their R&D costs [37]. Consequently, pharmaceutical companies are reluctant to disclose their technology, and there are significant financial motivations for them to utilize patents as a mean to constrain the R&D endeavors of their rivals. These practices discourage subsequent R&D activities, leading to a substitution of R&D investments [38]. Additionally, empirical evidence presented by Galasso [39] highlights the challenges of coordination between patent applicants and subsequent researchers in the pharmaceutical market.
In addition, let us consider the potential outcomes of firms opting for different research line. Given the divergence in R&D tracks among firms, the patenting activities of one firm do not impede the R&D efforts of others. Consequently, the R&D market could achieve greater economic efficiency. Regrettably, as highlighted by Kong et al. [40], Chinese pharmaceutical companies exhibit a relatively uniform product pipeline, with many companies concentrating on a single therapeutic area (oncology) and employing similar technologies. This has led to significant overlap in the research lines of pharmaceutical companies, resulting in a high level of substitution in their R&D investments. Consequently, Chinese biopharmaceutical companies are facing intense competition characterized by a lack of diversity in the market. Presently, the negative consequences of business stealing effect are amplified, while the beneficial impacts of natural spillover are reduced. This results in negative spillover consequences.
2.5 Hypotheses
To summarize the fundamental ideas of these theoretical analyses, we propose the following hypotheses:
1. Hypothesis 1 (H1): There exists strategic substitutes in R&D investments among Chinese biopharmaceutical companies.
2. Hypothesis 2 (H2): If R&D investments exhibit strategic substitutes, then endogenous knowledge spillover effects will hinder the improvement of innovation performance in biopharmaceutical companies.
3. Hypothesis 3 (H3): The patent race paradigm and excessive concentration in the research lines are sources of strategic substitutes in R&D strategies, exacerbating the negative impact of spillover effects on innovation activities of pharmaceutical companies.
It is evident that H1 serves as a premise, H2 posits hypotheses regarding the consequences of spillover effects, and H3 delves into the underlying reasons.
3. Data
3.1 Sample
We utilize data from Chinese biopharmaceutical A-share listed companies spanning the years 2005 to 2020 as the basis for our research. The financial information of these enterprises is sourced from CSMAR and CCER economic and financial databases, while their industry categorization is established in accordance with the 2021 version of industry classification standards by SHENYIN & WANGUO FUTURES Co., Ltd. Considering the time required for patents to be cited, the data is accurate as of the end of 2020. The patent data utilized in this study is sourced from the PatSnap Database, Google Patent Search System, and the Patent Search System offered by the China National Intellectual Property Administration (CNIPA).
During the patent information retrieval process, we employ the complete name of the company in both Chinese and English languages for conducting the search. The search encompassing patent offices across 164 countries (regions) globally, encompassing patents with legal statuses such as disclosure, substantive examination, authorization, before expiration of time limit, non-payment of the annual fee, restoration of the right, and partially invalid patents. It excludes patents with legal statuses of rejection, withdrawal, invalid application, abandonment, and other legal statuses.
In the procedure of aligning corporate financial data with patent data, we utilize the complete enterprise name as a distinctive identifier for the matching process. This involves employing a string-matching algorithm based on the Python 3.9 interpreter, enabling the integration of corporate financial data with patent data. Subsequently, the patent Pub. No. is employed as a unique identifier to link the original patent with its forward and backward citing patents. Ultimately, the aggregate count of patents identified amounts to approximately 683,555, encompassing both the primary patent data and its forward and backward citations.
Tables Z1-Z3 in S1 File presents the detailed patent information subsequent to the matching procedure.
3.2 Variables
3.2.1 Patent activity.
In accordance with Trajtenberg [41], employing citation-weighted patents as a surrogate measure for the patent activities (or innovation outputs) of a firm. PatCited is determined by adding the quantity of invention patents and utility model patents, as well as the quantity of their forward citations. And a greater number of citation-weighted patents indicates the increased economic and technological significance of the patents. Correspondingly, we can measure the patenting activity of other firms in the market and therefore define the variable OPCit as the citation-weighted patents of other firms in the market.
3.2.2 R&D stock (or intellectual capital).
Refer to the classical method of Hall [42] to calculate the firm’s research and development (R&D) stock:(19)where the rate of depreciation δ = 15% which aligns with the approach of Hall [42] and Pang et al. [43]. And initial firm R&D stock is defined as:(20)where RDj0 is the firm j’s R&D in the first year of the sample period, and g is the average growth rate of R&D investment in the sample period. From this, we can derive the R&D stock of the company for each year. We estimate the overall quantity of R&D stock within the sector but excluding firm i, i.e., , lnRdStockjt indicates the R&D stock of a particular firm j. The identical rationale results in lnORDit (= ).
3.2.3 Endogenous knowledge spillover.
The portfolio of patents submitted by a company provides valuable insights into the company’s R&D technology emphasis and knowledge management strategies. We regard patenting as a mechanism through which firms can protect their knowledge. For instance, if a company seeks a patent for the treatment and prevention of breast cancer (IPC Classification No. A61K36/8905), it signifies that the company is engaged in R&D activities within the technical domain of A61K (thus delineating the technical scope of the company’s R&D endeavors), has achieved specific outcomes, and aims to safeguard these R&D outcomes from infringement by submitting a patent application (or aims to prevent competitors from exploiting these R&D outcomes for financial gain, which underscores the nature of endogenous knowledge spillovers).
In the computation of spillover effects, our approach is followed by the research conducted by the work of Jaffe et al. [44] and Lucking et al. [45]. The k-dimensional column vector Si,T= (Si,1,T,Si,2,T,Si,3,T,…,Si,k,T)′ represents the patent share matrix of firm i in all technology subclasses in the T period (2005–2020). In the formula, Si,k,T indicates the share of patents of firm i in the technology subclass k in period T. We define Si,k,T by calculating the ratio of the number of IPC codes (3-digit) to the total number of IPC codes (also 3-digit), where duplicate IPC codes in one patent were removed. Normalize the column vector Si,k,T and then obtain Si,T, i.e., . The technical proximity of firm i and firms j is the dot product of their standardized patent share matrices. In the calculation process, in order to prevent the incorporation of self-funded R&D investment as an external source of knowledge transfer in the knowledge spillover matrix, we assume that a firm’s technological proximity to itself is 0 (i.e., ). Finally, by multiplying the technological proximity between two firms by the intellectual capital stock of firm j, one spillover variable is obtained. There are various firms in the market, and we engage in a comparable mathematical procedure where we aggregate these values (see Eq (21)). In the context of regression analysis, the derived spillover variable is divided by a factor of 1000 in order to reduce the magnitude of the unit difference between the variables.(21)where .
In our analysis, we derive the technology proximity matrix by exclusively considering the patents filed by firms within the same industry as the focal firm. This approach incorporates competition effects into the assessment of spillovers, aligning with the theoretical framework we have developed.
3.2.4 Technology gap.
The technology gap (TechGap) refers to the disparity in total factor productivity between a specific firm and a leading-edge technology firm. The LP method, as proposed by Levinsohn and Petrin [46], is employed to compute the total factor productivity of all firms. Subsequently, the disparity in TFP between a specific firm and a technologically advanced firm is determined. Initially, as demonstrated in Eq (22), the production function is established as:(22)
In the formula, lnYit、lnKit、lnLit、lnMit are the natural logarithm of the actual operating income, net fixed assets, number of employees and intermediate input of the enterprise respectively. And SOEit is a dummy variable indicates the nature of the property right (if it is a state-owned enterprise, the value is 1, otherwise the value is 0), τyear, υprov, φind are fixed effects of year, province and industry respectively. In the computation, the operating income is adjusted using the producer price index for pharmaceutical industrial products. The intermediate input is represented as the sum of operating costs and selling, administrative, and financial expenses, then reduced by the depreciation and amortization in the current period and the cash disbursed to employees. By estimating Eq (22), we can obtain the TFP of each firm. Further, the concept of the technology gap is delineated as stated by Aghion et al. [47]:(23)(24)where TFPmt is the largest TFP in the sample, and TFPit is the TFP of firm i in the t period. If an enterprise is at the forefront of technology, the gap between the enterprise and the second largest TFPm−1,t is used as the measurement standard for technology gap.
3.2.5 Herfindahl-Hirschman Index.
The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) is frequently employed as a metric for assessing market structure or concentration. A higher HHI value indicates a more concentrated market. The calculation of HHI typically involves the use of operating revenue in Eq (25).(25)where HHIjt denotes the concentration of industry j in year t, Yijt denotes the operating income of firm i in industry j in year t, and Xjt denotes the sum of operating income of all firms in industry j in year t. denotes the market share of firm i. The HHI is calculated by summing the squares of the market shares of all enterprises in the market.
3.2.6 Patent originality.
The originality of a patent is determined by analyzing the backward citation information of the original patent [48]:(26)where BCitedq is the total number of backward citations of patent q, and BCitedqk is the number of backward citations of the patent in the technology subclass k. The latter item in the formula reflects the concentration of backward citations of a patent, and generally speaking, the lower the concentration, the higher the originality of the patent. Patent originality (Origin) at the firm level is the average of all patents filed by firm i in period t.
(27)
The greater the patent originality index, the more receptive the organization is to assimilating knowledge from patents and other domains, and leveraging diverse knowledge combinations to drive innovation in the development of patented inventions. Calculating the mean value of patent originality for a firm is a straightforward and efficient method. In our way of calculation, the patent originality data we gained has a bimodal distribution, which means that one peak is close to zero and the other peak is greater than zero. The median or plurality inadequately captures the general situation in the presence of this data distribution. Averaging can account for all samples, even if certain contain extreme values; however, excessive bias can be substantially avoided through the implementation of tail-shrinking in data processing.
3.3 Descriptive statistics
In order to guarantee the accuracy and comprehensiveness of the data, the research samples are managed in the following manner: Samples with listing status of ST, *ST, suspended, or delisted in the present year are omitted. Furthermore, samples with incomplete observations for more than three consecutive years are also excluded. For instance, in the case of a specific enterprise variable, if the value of said variable is absent for three consecutive years, the data pertaining to the enterprise for these three consecutive years is omitted from the sample. We employ a comparable screening process for all variables. Utilizing the random forest algorithm, multiple imputation was conducted to select a dataset that maintains the original data distribution and exhibits a mean change of less than 5%. This approach aims to uphold the utmost integrity and accuracy of the data for analysis. All continuous variables undergo a 1% shrink-tail adjustment before and after to mitigate the impact of outliers on the empirical findings. Following this adjustment, a final unbalanced panel data set comprising 2,863 firm-year observations for 341 A-share listed companies is derived.
The variable names and symbols utilized in this paper are explicitly described in Table 1.The descriptive statistics of the variables discussed in this study are presented in Table 2. Detailed definitions of variables can be found in the Table Z4 in S1 File. The data utilized in this study, along with the regression code developed, are available in S1 Data.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Table 2 provides basic information regarding the sample of enterprises. With respect to firm size, the sample comprises over 50% large-scale enterprises and a minority small and medium-sized enterprises, according to the firm size criteria established by the Chinese government. This is because our firm information primarily comes from publicly traded corporations, all of which have certain size. Regarding the nature of enterprise ownership, over 50% of the enterprises in the sample are privately owned, while a small number are state-owned. From a perspective of enterprise profitability, the majority of enterprises have a positive return on assets (ROA), which suggests that they are able to efficiently utilize their assets for profitable endeavors. Only a small minority of enterprises have a negative ROA. In terms of enterprise R&D investment, all sampled enterprises make annual investments in R&D, and the standard deviation of the pertinent variables reveals clear disparities between the magnitude of R&D investment and the stock of intellectual capital. When it comes to firms’ patent applications, there is a significant disparity in their capacity to obtain patents. The majority of enterprises may only submit applications for fewer than 15 patents annually, while a very small fraction can apply for more than 800 patents. Likewise, there exists a significant disparity in the quality and originality of patents. This can be observed in the significant variability of variables such as PatCited and Origin, as indicated by their substantial standard deviations. Concerning knowledge spillovers, the magnitude in the spillover variable from 0 to 4.49 indicates that there are substantial differences between organizations in terms of spillovers. Simultaneously, it exhibits a moderate standard deviation, further confirming the considerable disparity in spillovers among enterprises.
4. Empirical analysis
4.1 Assessing preconditions: Is there a potential for substitution in R&D among companies?
To initiate the empirical analysis, we begin by assessing the validity of H1. Specifically, we establish four equations as a foundation for this assessment. Eq (28), Eq (29), and Eq (30) investigate the potential substitution or complementary between research and development (R&D) investment, intellectual capital, and patent applications within firms, while Eq (31) examines the influence of competitors’ R&D investment on the change in operating income of a specific firm. Upon closer examination, these equations are interconnected and collectively depict the line of a firm from R&D to product sales. In the regression analysis, the coefficients of interest are denoted as , , and .
(28)(29)(30)(31)
When selecting control variables, we select variables that indicate characteristics that might potentially affect the R&D activities and patent application behavior of the organization. Specifically, we control the scale of the enterprise (scale) [49], the nature of the property (SOE), debt asset ratio (Lev), return on assets (ROA), circulating rate of total asset (Turnover), and the external competitive environment (HHI). At the same time, the fixed effect of firm (ηi), year (τyear) and industry (φInd) is also controlled in the regression. To simplify the expression of the equations, we use ϕijt to represent these three fixed effects. We argue that incorporating several fixed effects and adding control variables from a multidimensional perspective can assist us in mitigating the problem of endogeneity.
The results of the regression analysis are presented in Table 3. The estimation of coefficient indicates a significant strategic substitution of R&D investment among firms, with a statistically significant impact at the 1% level (see Table 3 Column (1)). The analysis reveals a strong investment substitution, with a 1% increase in total industry investment leading to a 50.7% reduction in the investment of a specific firm, suggesting a substantial effect. If the presence of investment from competing firms leads to a decrease in the investment made by a particular firm, it will also result in a reduction in the firm’s stock of intellectual capital and patent output. Table 3 Columns (2), (3) provide additional evidence supporting the robustness of this finding, showing that the stock of intellectual capital and patent applications of other firms significantly suppresses the relevant output of a given firm at the 5% and 1% significance levels, respectively. Additionally, Table 3 Column (4) demonstrates that R&D investment by other firms diminishes firm-specific operating income. These results are consistent with theoretical expectations and provide evidence for the existence of R&D investment substitutions.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Naturally, endogeneity is still not entirely circumvented. To assess the influence of these problems on the results, we repeat the regression by incorporating lagging one period explanatory variables and show the results in the Table Z5 in S1 File. This can significantly improve the robustness of the results.
4.2 Baseline estimates and results
Theoretical analysis indicates that if H1 is valid, then H2 will also naturally be valid. A patent equation is developed to assess the validity of H2,(32)
further transformations yield:(33)
PatCitedit represents the number of citation-weighted patents obtained by enterprise i in period t, which is the explained variable. Spillit is the surrogate variable of the knowledge spillover effect, which is the main explanatory variable in our model. The remaining variables carry the same significance as previously described. For estimation, we use the high-dimensional fixed-effect Poisson pseudo-maximum likelihood method (PPMLHDFE).
It is important to note that a commonly used estimation method involves taking the logarithm of the sum of the number of patents or citation-weighted patents plus one, and then conducting linear regression (“log one plus” regression). However, these models are prone to biased and inconsistent regression estimates due to the presence of heteroskedasticity, and may yield incorrect regression coefficient signs. Even when controlling for fixed effects, there is a likelihood of upward or downward bias, and the estimation coefficient of the zero value may lack practical economic implications [50]. In contrast, Poisson regression using pseudo-maximum likelihood estimation avoids these issues and makes fewer statistical assumptions about the distribution of the explained variables. Additionally, the accelerated HDFE–GIRLS algorithm enables the inclusion of multidimensional fixed effects in the model, thereby enhancing the efficiency of estimation [51]. In order to highlight the differences between the traditional method and the PPMLHDFE technique, we initially utilized the OLS method in the benchmark regressions, but later transitioned to using PPMLHDFE as the primary estimation method.
Table 4 shows the estimate results of these baseline models. Estimates of the patent equation suggest that the knowledge spillover will lead to a decrease in the quantity of patents weighted by citations, with a hazard ratio of 0.691 (e−0.370 = 0.691<1) or 0.677(e−0.390 = 0.677<1). This serves to validate the H2 (significant at 1% or 5%, Table 4, column (3) and (4)). Table 4 Columns (1) and (2) report OLS estimation, in line with standard methodology. The OLS regression results also validate the robustness of the conclusions. In conclusion, our analysis suggests that the spillover effects obstacle the innovation efforts of pharmaceutical firms, resulting in a decrease in the citation-weighed patents.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
4.3 Robustness
4.3.1 Endogeneity.
The potential endogeneity in the patent equation can be attributed to three main factors: Firstly, there may be inaccuracies in measuring knowledge spillovers, with the inclusion of rent spillovers potentially leading to endogeneity issues in the model [53]. Secondly, the confusion of cause and effect may arise from external shocks or other confounding factors, such as positive external R&D shocks leading to an increase in R&D investment by all firms in the industry, which could be mistakenly attributed to the positive effects of knowledge spillovers [31]. Thirdly, the endogeneity of technological linkages between firms may raise concerns about the endogeneity of knowledge spillovers in the model [11]. Hence, in accordance with the study by Yang et al. [54], a shift-share instrumental variable (SSIV) was constructed and the baseline model was re-estimated using the control function method as outlined by Wooldridge [55].
The SSIV is computed by following the subsequent steps. Firstly, take year to as the base period and calculate the industry R&D growth rate in year t relative to year to. After that, the R&D input of enterprises in each year is discounted according to the calculated industry R&D growth rate, and the R&D stock is further calculated. Finally, the original R&D matrix is replaced by the above-calculated-to R&D matrix during the calculation of the knowledge spillover proxy variables. The R&D industry growth rate is treated as an exogenous shock, which satisfies the exogeneity condition, and the initial value of R&D is the firm’s actual R&D input, which satisfies the relevance conditions.
The results of the regressions are presented in Table 5. The results of the estimation indicate that the issue of endogeneity is not of significant concern (note that the estimated coefficient on v2h_fe is not significant) in the patent equation and the above conclusions are robust.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
4.3.2 Additional robustness checks.
Subsequently, we conducted various robustness tests to assess the reliability of the findings, and the regression results are detailed in the Tables Z6-Z8 in S1 File.
Considering government subsidies (lnsub), financing constraints (KZ) [56] and financial leverage (FL). Government subsidies plays a significant role in influencing firms’ decisions to innovate, as it provides crucial incentives for innovation [57, 58]. In order to assess the impact of these subsidies on innovation, we incorporate the government subsidy variable into the baseline equations. The regression findings indicate that government subsidies can enhance the number of citation-weighted patents held by firms at a statistically significant level of 5% or 10%, aligning with theoretical perspectives. It is important to highlight that the inclusion of subsidies in the regression does not alter the coefficients for Spill.
Brown et al. [59] assert that the R&D activities of young high-tech firms are influenced by cash flow and external equity. The presence of financing constraints is identified as a significant factor impacting R&D in high-tech firms. When incorporating the financing constraint variable into the regression analysis, the findings indicate that such constraints lead to an increase in firms’ R&D stock. This implies that heightened external financing constraints may prompt pharmaceutical companies to prioritize internal capital accumulation as an alternative to external financing in order to enhance R&D investment. It is noteworthy that the sign and magnitude of the primary explanatory variables of interest exhibit minimal change following the inclusion of the financing constraint variable. Furthermore, the coefficients of the primary explanatory variables remain largely unaffected even after the introduction of the financial leverage variable into the regression equation. Notably, financial leverage appears to have limited influence on corporate R&D behavior.
Redefine the explanatory variables. Given that the 3-digit IPC classification lacks precision and fails to adequately capture the diversity of patents within the category [60], we propose recalculating the technology proximity matrix using a 4-digit IPC in order to derive new variables (Spill4) for knowledge spillover in the patent equation. Furthermore, taking into account the impact of knowledge spillovers in relation to boundaries and distance [61–63], as well as the presence of cross-industry spillovers [64, 65], we propose a redefinition of two metrics for measuring knowledge spillovers. One approach involves mitigating the spillover effect based on distance (techgeo_spill), while the other aims to capture cross-industry spillovers through the analysis of forward and backward citations of the original patent (inter_spill). When altering the metrics of the primary explanatory factors, it is observed that knowledge spillovers continue to inhibit the increase in citation-weighted patents.
Redefine the explained variables. The citation-weighted patents may exhibit time-truncated impacts. We conducted additional regressions using the quantity of patents as the independent variable. The findings indicate that this adjustment does not alter the primary findings of the study.
Modify the configuration of the model form. First, we try to include more fixed effects in the benchmark models. As a result, the significance and size of the regression coefficients for the main explanatory variables remain virtually unchanged after we additionally include province as well as province & industry interaction fixed effects. Furthermore, we modify the clustering level by considering the interaction between year and industry. Subsequently, we also explore alternative regression methods including negative binomial regression, panel fixed effects regression, and panel Poisson regression. It is important to note that the fundamental findings of this study remain consistent despite variations in the model setup and regression techniques employed.
4.4 Mechanism
In our theoretical analysis, we posit that the strategic substitutions of R&D investments arise from the dynamics of patent races and excessive concentration in the R&D sector, leading to the dissemination of adverse spillover effects (as outlined in H3). As direct measurement of the R&D race pattern is challenging, we can infer the impact of the patent race (R&D competition) by assessing the technology gap between firms and the concentration of the product market. Additionally, due to limitations in available data, the specific research line chosen by each biopharmaceutical firm is not precisely known, however, we can speculate on whether firms pursue distinct research lines by examining the originality of the patents they file. To further investigate the reliability of the theoretical mechanism analysis, we elaborate on a moderated effects model.(34)where Mechanit are the moderator variables, which can be TechGap,HHI or Origin. We also use the PPMLHDFE method for estimation. The estimates are presented in Table 6, while Figs 1–3 provide a detailed illustration of the influence of the moderator variables.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Note: In these pictures, the horizontal axis is the mechanism variable, and the vertical axis is the change of one standard deviation of the mechanism variable that brings about the change in g(PatCitedit). The dashed lines in the figures show the upper and lower bounds of the confidence intervals, and the solid lines indicate the size of the spillover effects. The bottom histogram shows the distribution of moderating variables, with the vertical lines being the dividing lines between significant and non-significant, the labels NS being insignificant, and the labeling Sig being significant. If there is no vertical line, it means that it is significant in all intervals. All confidence levels in the figures default to 5%, and it was tested that using a higher confidence level (e.g. 1%) did not change the conclusions of this paper at all. The STATA program for picture production comes from Kaufman [66].
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Table 6 Column (1) indicates a positive moderating impact of technology gaps on spillover effects. This suggests that companies with greater technology gaps will experience more adverse consequences from spillovers. Further elaboration is available in Fig 1. It has been observed that spillover effects have an insignificant impact on firms’ innovation endeavors when the technology gap is less than 0.274. This finding is based on a small subset of our data, and given the small technology gap, these firms are likely to be the industry leaders in terms of technology. Conversely, when the technology gap exceeds or equals 0.274, the adverse effects of spillovers become apparent, affecting the majority of firms. This suggests that the outcomes of R&D competition differ for successful and unsuccessful firms. The victors, namely the select few major technology companies with narrower technology gaps, are able to achieve initial success in R&D and secure patents. These firms exhibit minimal substitutes in their R&D investments and are relatively unaffected by knowledge spillovers. Conversely, the less successful entities, specifically the firms with wider technology gaps, are not as fortunate. They are unable to capitalize on R&D achievements and patent applications, and instead face reductions in R&D investment due to substitutions, as well as unrecoverable costs resulting from unsuccessful endeavors. These findings align with the theoretical analysis presented in the preceding section.
Table 6 column (2) shows that market concentration has a negative moderating effect on spillovers. This indicates that as market concentration decreases, indicating a more competitive market, the negative effects of spillovers become more pronounced. Conversely, when market concentration reaches or exceeds 0.878, spillovers cease to have a significant impact, and vice versa. (as depicted in Fig 2). Given the interrelation between the product market and the R&D market, as indicated in our theoretical analysis, heightened competition in the product market is likely to result in intensified competition in R&D. Consequently, it is plausible to posit that increased R&D competition facilitates the propagation of negative spillover effects. This further implies that R&D competition is a contributing factor to the observed negative impact of spillovers on innovative activity.
Table 6 column (3) shows that firms’ patent originality has a negative moderating effect on spillovers. This suggests that as a company’s patents become more unique, or as the company pursues a distinct research line, the negative spillover effect diminishes. Furthermore, the significance shifts when originality exceeds or equals 0.285 (as depicted in Fig 3). This implies that specific companies with higher originality can withstand the adverse effects of spillovers, which only represent a small portion of all firms in the sector. These analyses indicate that if a company is capable of pursuing a unique research line, it will experience minimal or no negative impact from spillovers. This underscores that the concentration of the research line is the underlying cause of the adverse impact of spillovers.
According to these analyses, we provide indirect confirmation that the patent race paradigm and the excessive concentration of R&D tracks are the underlying factors contributing to the spread of spillovers, thus supporting the validity of hypothesis H3.
4.5 Heterogeneity
In the benchmark model, it is assumed that spillover effects uniformly impact all firms. However, the theoretical analysis in Section 2 of this paper and the empirical tests in the preceding section indicate that the dynamics of patenting competitions, wherein some firms succeed while others do not, significantly contribute to the adverse consequences of spillovers. Specifically, firms that are unsuccessful in R&D competitions are more susceptible to the negative effects of spillovers. The identification of the firms that are likely to be unsuccessful in R&D competitions is crucial. We anticipate that the outcome of these competitions may be influenced by factors such as firm ownership, size, and technological characteristics. To investigate these variations, we conduct a re-estimation of the standard model using a divided sample.
Table 7 demonstrates the estimation results of the heterogeneity analysis. The estimation results in Table 7 Columns (1) and (2) differentiate the impact of firm ownership on the observed phenomena. The findings indicate that private firms (see column (1)) are more significantly influenced by negative spillover effects compared to state-owned firms (see column (2)). This disparity can be attributed to the financial backing provided to state-owned enterprises (SOEs) by the local or central government, their robust R&D capabilities, and their monopoly market power, which enables them to pursue multiple R&D directions to mitigate the risk of competitive failure. Furthermore, even in the event of failure, SOEs benefit from government support. In contrast, private firms lack these advantages and consequently face a higher risk of failure.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
The estimation results in Table 7 Columns (3) and (4) differentiate the impact of spillovers on enterprises of varying magnitudes. The findings indicate that small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) (see column (4)) experience a more pronounced and statistically significant negative impact from spillovers compared to large firms (see column (3)). The continuous nature of R&D activities holds crucial importance for pharmaceutical companies. Large firms have more stable funding sources for R&D, whereas SMEs have relatively limited funding options. Consequently, SMEs are at a financial disadvantage in competing with large firms and are more likely to suffer from the negative effects of spillovers, making them disadvantaged in the patent race.
The results of the estimation in Table 7 Columns (5) and (6) differentiate the technological characteristics of the firms. It is evident that high-tech firms (see column (6)) are less influenced by spillovers and have less significance compared to non-high-tech firms (see column (5)). High-tech firms engage in R&D activities, possess a well-established R&D infrastructure, exhibit greater R&D experience, and are likely to receive R&D subsidies from the government. These factors enhance the capacity of high-tech firms to assimilate knowledge [67, 68] and manage R&D risks more effectively. Conversely, non-high-tech firms lack these advantages, necessitating more exploration and R&D efforts to achieve similar R&D outcomes. Consequently, non-high-tech firms face a higher risk of R&D competitive failure and experience a more pronounced negative impact from spillovers. In summary, private enterprises, small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs), and non-high-tech enterprises are disadvantaged in R&D competition and are adversely affected by spillover effects.
5. Policy implications
In this section, we analyze the policy implications arising from the findings presented in this paper. Our focus is on identifying the necessary mechanisms for enhancing the innovation performance of biomedical markets.
5.1 "Loser’s subsidies"
The patent race paradigm is identified as a fundamental contributor to distorting spillovers, which in turn discourages firms from engaging in innovation. It is important to note that the solution does not lie in the complete elimination of biomedical patents, nor does it entail excessively elevating patent protection. Rather, it is imperative to undertake essential reforms to the patent system. Initially, it is essential for research and development (R&D) subsidies and the patent system to work in conjunction with each other. The current patent framework results in private enterprises, small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs), and non-high-tech enterprises being disadvantaged in the R&D competition, as they are affected by spillover effects and have weaker incentives for R&D. Consequently, it is imperative to implement a "loser’s subsidy" to address this issue. This subsidy would serve to reward firms engaged in R&D, irrespective of their success, with a specific focus on those with high R&D potential that have not yet achieved success. The objective is to nurture emerging innovative firms for future pharmaceutical innovation and to establish a conducive R&D environment. It is important to note that a loser’s subsidy does not entail a reduction in patenting standards or a bias towards technology-following firms. Acemoglu and Akcigit [69] contend that favoring technology-following firms in patent protection would lead to decreased innovation efficiency. Therefore, there is a need to guard the threshold for patenting to avoid the negative impact of " Bad money drives out good".
5.2 Reallocation of R&D resources
The excessive concentration of R&D activities in specific areas can also lead to distorted spillover effects. When a significant number of firms focus their R&D efforts in the same area, it can result in inefficiencies and may not be responsive to changes in market demand. To tackle these obstacles, it is imperative for governments to facilitate the market mechanism to ensure that the price mechanism accurately reflects shifts in market demand. In cases where there is an urgent need for certain medications or medical equipment, patients exhibit a greater willingness to pay, leading to higher market prices. Consequently, enterprises can adapt their R&D strategies and alter their R&D focus promptly in response to the pricing dynamics of their products in the pharmaceutical market, thereby preventing excessive concentration of enterprises in the R&D sector. On the contrary, the risk associated with R&D may serve as a significant deterrent for enterprises to transition to new research lines. Additionally, the investment in R&D fixed assets, considered as a sunk cost, may impede enterprises from venturing into new R&D avenues. State-owned firms, universities, research institutions, and other public sectors need to emphasize and strengthen their efforts in basic research. They should also actively participate in joint research and development initiatives with enterprises that are at the forefront of applied research. This approach aims to mitigate the risk associated with enterprise R&D and enhance innovation output [70, 71]. Furthermore, the government should consider implementing a system of accelerated depreciation of fixed assets and providing moderate subsidies for the procurement of R&D assets, which would contribute to enhancing industrial innovation performance [72].
5.3 Competition policy adjustments
In the theoretical analysis, it is observed that heightened market competition is associated with diminished innovation performance, particularly leading to the dissemination of spillover effects. In the context of pharmaceutical firms, the protracted R&D cycle and substantial capital outlay in biopharmaceuticals necessitate ensuring the sustained investment in R&D. Otherwise, prior efforts may be rendered futile. And corporate profits serve as a crucial funding source for corporate R&D endeavors. Consequently, it is imperative to establish a stable market competition environment, elevate the market access threshold moderately, and rigorously enforce the access system for pharmaceutical companies. On the other hand, it is essential to regulate the competitive conduct of businesses in order to prevent unfair competition and rent-seeking behavior, and to establish a standardized and orderly framework for market competition. This necessitates the implementation of anti-monopoly measures by the government to prohibit market position abuse, market action coordination, and monopolistic pricing. Additionally, it requires the enhancement of market competition regulations, and prohibition of unregulated drug production and sales practices. These systems and regulations hold significant importance in enhancing social welfare, as they can help rectify the imbalance between low-end surplus and high-end deficit in China’s pharmaceutical production, and ensure the safety of medicinal products, thereby safeguarding public health.
6. Conclusion and discussion
This study discusses the impact of endogenous knowledge spillovers on the innovation endeavors of biopharmaceutical companies. In competitive market settings, knowledge spillovers exhibit a "Janus face" effect, and the pharmaceutical innovation landscape in China is progressing towards the phase of original innovation, prompting a reevaluation of the implications of spillovers. To investigate these impacts, we construct a two-stage research and development (R&D) game model that permits interconnected competition in upstream R&D markets and downstream product markets, and necessitates that firms’ R&D investments must consider competitors’ R&D activities. Drawing on the outcomes of the game, we formulate research hypotheses and compile a novel dataset to examine the applicability of the theoretical analysis. In the section dedicated to econometric analysis, we assess whether the theoretical hypotheses align with empirical evidence and investigate the mechanisms and heterogeneity, subsequently proposing policy implications based on the findings. The findings of this research indicate:
* In competitive market environments, the impact of endogenous knowledge spillovers on the innovative endeavors of firms is contingent upon the strategic complementarity or substitutions of R&D investments among firms. When R&D investments among firms are strategically complementary, spillovers are likely to foster innovation. Conversely, in cases where they are strategic substitutes, spillovers are expected to deter firms from engaging in innovative activities.
* The strategic complementarity of R&D investments represents a broader scenario, and empirical studies often provide evidence that spillovers encourage firms to engage in innovation. Under specific circumstances, the strategic substitutions of R&D investments also apply. In the biopharmaceutical market, this substitution is driven by the competitive nature of patent races among firms and the over-concentration of corporate research lines, which can amplify the adverse effects of spillovers.
* Spillover effects have varying impacts on different types of enterprises. In particular, private firms, small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs), and non-high-tech firms are adversely affected by spillovers. This is due to the higher likelihood of these firms failing in the R&D competition, resulting in increased substitutions of R&D investments under the patent race paradigm and consequently leading to greater negative spillover effects.
* In order to mitigate the negative effects of spillovers, several policy innovations are necessary. One such innovation is the implementation of a "loser’s subsidy" to foster a more permissive R&D environment and cultivate a new generation of innovators to enhance the industry’s innovation performance. Another necessary measure involves the redistribution of R&D resources to prevent the excessive concentration of R&D activities, mitigate intense homogenized competition, and rectify the imbalance of "low-end surplus and high-end insufficiency" in pharmaceutical supply. Additionally, adjustments to competition policy are essential to establish a favorable market competition environment and prevent the excessive erosion of profits for established enterprises by raising the market access threshold, thereby ensuring the quality of pharmaceutical supply.
Discussion of these results would be interesting. To the best of our knowledge, the notion that "knowledge spillovers motivate firms to innovate" is well supported by a number of researchers. For instance, Holl et al. [5] discovered that the local knowledge spillover has a beneficial effect on the firm’s constant innovation. Braunerhjelm et al. demonstrate that the spread of knowledge through the movement of workers promotes the innovation initiatives for companies [73]. Nevertheless, our research keeps a skeptical attitude towards these perspectives and asserts that specific market condition elements have the potential to disrupt the otherwise beneficial impacts of spillovers. Our research presents compelling evidence that the knowledge spillover in the biopharmaceutical market does not result in a significant increase in innovative activities. This might be linked to fierce competition within the market. The Chinese biopharmaceutical market is saturated with firms that concentrate on similar R&D fields and adopt parallel research lines. This results in fierce competition among firms, and it appears that the degree of competition does not contribute to the success of firms’ R&D efforts. We present empirical evidence that exhibits parallels with the findings of Audretsch and Belitski [24]. Their research discover a correlation between knowledge spillovers and corporate innovation that follows an inverted U-shaped pattern. They also identify market competition as a significant factor contributing to the inhibition of innovation caused by spillovers. Our empirical results are also consistent with the findings of Bryan et al. [26], who indicate that intense competition in the biomedical industry distorts the direction of R&D, leading to a reduction in social welfare.
Policies such as "loser subsidies" have been suggested in this paper as a way to enhance the innovation performance of the biopharmaceutical market in China. Nevertheless, it is imperative that we use prudence when implementing these policies. Firstly, their applicability is limited in extent. The biopharmaceutical market in China is experiencing an evolution, moving towards a phase of original innovation. The term "transition period" denotes a phase in which the industry’s focus is on enhancing the quality of innovations rather than only growing their quantity. Furthermore, the implementation of these policies necessitates an appropriate industrial framework, encompassing the construction of a modern pharmaceutical industry system, an existing institutional foundation, and a particular emphasis on pharmaceutical intellectual property rights. If the biopharmaceutical industry of a developing country is in its early stages, it may be more advantageous to adopt imitations policies, since they may speed the growth of innovative technologies. Market-oriented policies will be useless in a country that lacks the institutional foundation of a market. Beyond that, the implementation of policies to enhance the intensity of intellectual property rights (IPR) protection should be balanced to a country’s existing R&D capabilities. An excessive focus on IPR protection might hinder subsequent innovation, but a complete absence of safeguards for property rights is not conducive to significant advancements in innovation. In addition, in order to prevent false subsidies and stealing of subsidy funds by enterprises or R&D organizations, it is crucial to have a thorough understanding of the innovators when undertaking subsidy services.
Naturally, our study is subject to certain inherent constraints, which offer opportunities for further investigation. Primarily, our conclusions and policy suggestions are predicated on the premises of a competitive market and an imperfect patent system. Consequently, our research may have limited applicability in countries lacking a market-based system or where pharmaceutical patents are absent. It is advisable for developing nations in these circumstances to approach our findings with circumspection. Furthermore, despite the potential expansion of the existing data, it remains inadequate. Knowledge can be classified as either tacit or explicit, and references to patent literature typically only capture explicit knowledge exchanges, failing to adequately represent the transfer of tacit knowledge [74]. This issue highlights the need for future research endeavors. Subsequently, there is a necessity to develop improved methods for assessing tacit knowledge exchanges, which represents a significant area of interest for cutting-edge research. Finally, it is imperative for future studies to encompass a broader range of countries. The current paper lacks the ability to ascertain whether the findings are representative of the challenges faced by developing nations in general or are specific to the Chinese context. The ongoing investigation into pharmaceutical technology innovation underscores the necessity for additional empirical evidence to elucidate a trajectory for pharmaceutical technology advancement that aligns with the needs of the majority of developing countries.
Supporting information
S1 File.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0307171.s001
(DOCX)
S1 Data.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0307171.s002
(ZIP)
References
1. 1. Huang X. The pharmaceutical industry has leapt to the high end of the value chain. The State Council of the People’s Republic of China: Economic Daily; 2023 Dec. 14 [cited 2024 Jan. 30]. Available from: https://www.gov.cn/govweb/yaowen/liebiao/202312/content_6920238.htm.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
2. 2. Institute CMIIR, Market M. 2023 China Biopharmaceutical Industry Report. place unknown: publisher unknown; 2023 [cited 2023 Dec. 30]. Available from: https://file.vogel.com.cn/126/upload/resources/file/396704.pdf.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
3. 3. Ji J. From market chaos to innovation going global, how has China’s medical industry developed in the past 30 years? www.thepaper.cn: ThePaper; 2023 [cited 2024 Jan. 30]. Available from: https://www.thepaper.cn/newsDetail_forward_24999430.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
4. 4. Institute PIR. Analysis of the market size and development trend of China’s generic drug industry in 2021, and national policies to promote the high-quality development of the industry. place unknown: bg.qianzhan.com; 2022 [cited 2024 Jan. 30]. Available from: https://bg.qianzhan.com/report/detail/300/220328-ac2bb13f.html.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
5. 5. Adelheid H, Bettina P, Christian R. Local knowledge spillovers and innovation persistence of firms. Economics of Innovation and New Technology. 2023;32(6):826–50.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
6. 6. Czarnitzki D, Kraft K. Spillovers of innovation activities and their profitability. Oxford Economic Papers. 2012;64(2):302–22.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
7. 7. Thornton RA, Thompson P. Learning from experience and learning from others: An exploration of learning and spillovers in wartime shipbuilding. American Economic Review. 2001;91(5):1350–68.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
8. 8. Tseng C-Y, Pai D-C. Knowledge search, spillover and creation capability in India’s pharmaceutical industry. Technology Analysis & Strategic Management. 2014;26(2):207–22.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
9. 9. L E, B E, J A. The Impact of Knowledge Management and Knowledge Transfer in Growth and Innovation A Study of Business Start-Ups, Business Incubators and Business Accelerators. IFAC PapersOnLine. 2022;55(39):54–9.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
10. 10. Tzabbar D, Lee J, Seo D. Collaborative structure and post-mobility knowledge spillovers: A dyadic approach. Strategic Management Journal. 2022;43(9):1728–62.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
11. 11. Zacchia P. Knowledge spillovers through networks of scientists. The Review of Economic Studies. 2020;87(4):1989–2018.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
12. 12. Fershtman C, Gandal N. Direct and indirect knowledge spillovers: the “social network” of open‐source projects. The RAND Journal of Economics. 2011;42(1):70–91.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
13. 13. Coe DT, Helpman E, Hoffmaister AW. International R&D spillovers and institutions. European Economic Review. 2009;53(7):723–41.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
14. 14. Lucas RE Jr. On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics. 1988;22(1):3–42.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
15. 15. Lucas RE Jr. Ideas and growth. Economica. 2009;76(301):1–19.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
16. 16. Romer PM. Endogenous technological change. Journal of political Economy. 1990;98(5, Part 2):S71–S102.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
17. 17. Arrow KJ. The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing. The Review of Economic Studies. 1962;29(3):155–73.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
18. 18. Marshall A. The Substance of Economics. In: Marshall A, editor. Principles of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan UK; 2013. p. 12–23.
19. 19. Romer PM. Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth. Journal of Political Economy. 1986;94(5):1002–37.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
20. 20. Jacobs J. The economy of cities: Vintage; 2016.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
21. 21. Porter ME. Clusters and the new economics of competition. Harv Bus Rev. 1998;76(6):77–90. pmid:10187248
* View Article
* PubMed/NCBI
* Google Scholar
22. 22. Borjas GJ, Doran KB. Which peers matter? The relative impacts of collaborators, colleagues, and competitors. Review of economics and statistics. 2015;97(5):1104–17.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
23. 23. Arvanitis S, Seliger F, Woerter M. Knowledge spillovers, competition and innovation success. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics. 2020;82(5):1017–41.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
24. 24. Audretsch DB, Belitski M. The knowledge spillover of innovation. Industrial and Corporate Change. 2022;31(6):1329–57.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
25. 25. Sawada N. Technology gap matters on spillover. Review of Development Economics. 2010;14(1):103–20.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
26. 26. Bryan KA, Lemus J, Marshall G. R&D Competition and the Direction of Innovation. International Journal of Industrial Organization. 2022;82(2022):102841.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
27. 27. Gersbach H, Schmutzler A. Endogenous technological spillovers: causes and consequences. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy. 2003;12(2):179–205.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
28. 28. Shen B. The Influence of Endogenous Knowledge Spillovers on Open Innovation Cooperation Modes Selection. Wireless Personal Communications. 2018;102(4):2701–13.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
29. 29. Arque-Castells P, Spulber DF. Measuring the private and social returns to R&D: Unintended spillovers versus technology markets. Journal of Political Economy. 2022;130(7):1860–918.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
30. 30. Spulber DF. How do competitive pressures affect incentives to innovate when there is a market for inventions? Journal of Political Economy. 2013;121(6):1007–54.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
31. 31. Bloom N, Schankerman M, Van Reenen J. Identifying technology spillovers and product market rivalry. Econometrica. 2013;81(4):1347–93.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
32. 32. Spence M. Cost Reduction, Competition, and Industry Performance. Econometrica. 1984;52(1):101–21.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
33. 33. Klein MA. Secrecy, the patent puzzle and endogenous growth. European Economic Review. 2020;126:103445.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
34. 34. Loury GC. Market structure and innovation. The quarterly journal of economics. 1979:395–410.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
35. 35. Crepon B, Duguet E. Research and development, competition and innovation pseudo-maximum likelihood and simulated maximum likelihood methods applied to count data models with heterogeneity. Journal of econometrics. 1997;79(2):355–78.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
36. 36. Bessen J, Maskin E. Sequential innovation, patents, and imitation. The RAND Journal of Economics. 2009;40(4):611–35.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
37. 37. Grabowski H. Patents, Innovation and Access to New Pharmaceuticals. Journal of International Economic Law. 2002;5(4):849–60.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
38. 38. Macho‐Stadler I, Matsushima N, Shinohara R. Organizational structure and technological investment. The Journal of Industrial Economics. 2021;69(4):785–816.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
39. 39. Galasso A, Schankerman M. Patents and cumulative innovation: Causal evidence from the courts. The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 2015;130(1):317–69.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
40. 40. Kong L, Li Q, Kaitin KI, Shao L. Innovation in the Chinese pharmaceutical industry. Nature Reviews Drug Discovery. 2023;22(1):12–3. pmid:36303035
* View Article
* PubMed/NCBI
* Google Scholar
41. 41. Trajtenberg M. A penny for your quotes: patent citations and the value of innovations. The RAND Journal of Economics. 1990;21(1):172–87.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
42. 42. Hall BH. The manufacturing sector master file: 1959–1987. National Bureau of Economic Research Cambridge, Mass., USA; 1990 May 1990.
43. 43. Pang R, Tu X, Yan X. How do product market competition and knowledge spillover affect enterprise R&D? An empirical identification based on multi-dimensional proximity. Industrial Economics Research. 2021(02):1–14+29.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
44. 44. Jaffe AB. Technological opportunity and spillovers of R&D: evidence from firms’ patents, profits and market value. national bureau of economic research Cambridge, Mass., USA; 1986.
45. 45. Lucking B, Bloom N, Van Reenen J. Have R&D spillovers changed?: National Bureau of Economic Research; 2018.
46. 46. Levinsohn J, Petrin A. Estimating Production Functions Using Inputs to Control for Unobservables. The Review of Economic Studies. 2003;70(2):317–41.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
47. 47. Aghion P, Bloom N, Blundell R, Griffith R, Howitt P. Competition and innovation: An inverted-U relationship. The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 2005;120(2):701–28.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
48. 48. Trajtenberg M, Henderson R, Jaffe A. University versus corporate patents: A window on the basicness of invention. Economics of Innovation and New Technology. 1997;5(1):19–50.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
49. 49. China NBoSo. Statistical classification of micro, small, medium and large enterprises www.stats.gov.cn: National Bureau of Statistics of China; 2018 Jan. 03 [cited 2024 Jan. 30 2024 Jan. 30]. Available from: https://www.stats.gov.cn/sj/tjbz/gjtjbz/202302/t20230213_1902763.html.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
50. 50. Cohn JB, Liu Z, Wardlaw MI. Count (and count-like) data in finance. Journal of Financial Economics. 2022;146(2):529–51.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
51. 51. Correia S, Guimarães P, Zylkin T. Fast Poisson estimation with high-dimensional fixed effects. The Stata Journal. 2020;20(1):95–115.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
52. 52. Correia S. Singletons, cluster-robust standard errors and fixed effects: A bad mix. Technical Note, Duke University. 2015;7.
53. 53. Griliches Z. Issues in assessing the contribution of research and development to productivity growth. The Bell Journal of Economics. 1979;10(1):92–116.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
54. 54. Licheng Y, Zheng Z, Yunyun Z. Knowledge Spillover and Green Innovation: Moderating Effect of Institutional Pressure and Absorptive Capacity. Soft Science. 2023;37(09):67–77.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
55. 55. Wooldridge JM. Control function methods in applied econometrics. Journal of Human Resources. 2015;50(2):420–45.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
56. 56. Kaplan SN, Zingales L. Do Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities Provide Useful Measures of Financing Constraints?*. The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1997;112(1):169–215.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
57. 57. Arqué‐Castells P, Mohnen P. Sunk costs, extensive R&D subsidies and permanent inducement effects. The Journal of Industrial Economics. 2015;63(3):458–94.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
58. 58. Lach S. Do R&D subsidies stimulate or displace private R&D? Evidence from Israel. The journal of industrial economics. 2002;50(4):369–90.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
59. 59. BROWN JR, FAZZARI SM, PETERSEN BC. Financing Innovation and Growth: Cash Flow, External Equity, and the 1990s R&D Boom. The Journal of Finance. 2009;64(1):151–85.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
60. 60. Thompson P, Fox-Kean M. Patent citations and the geography of knowledge spillovers: A reassessment. American Economic Review. 2005;95(1):450–60.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
61. 61. Belenzon S, Schankerman M. Spreading the word: Geography, policy, and knowledge spillovers. Review of Economics and Statistics. 2013;95(3):884–903.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
62. 62. Li YA. Borders and distance in knowledge spillovers: Dying over time or dying with age?—Evidence from patent citations. European Economic Review. 2014;71:152–72.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
63. 63. Murata Y, Nakajima R, Okamoto R, Tamura R. Localized knowledge spillovers and patent citations: A distance-based approach. Review of Economics and Statistics. 2014;96(5):967–85.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
64. 64. Schnitzer M, Watzinger M. Measuring the Spillovers of Venture Capital. Review of Economics and Statistics. 2022;104(2):276–92.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
65. 65. Zhu P, Xiang G, Wang Y. R&D Spill-over Effects: Evidence from Chinese Industrial Sectors. Economic Research Journal. 2016;51(11):44–55.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
66. 66. Kaufman RL. Interaction effects in linear and generalized linear models: examples and applications using Stata: SAGE Publications, Inc.; 2019.
67. 67. Aguiar L, Gagnepain P. Absorptive capacity, knowledge spillovers and incentive contracts. International Journal of Industrial Organization. 2022;82:102830.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
68. 68. Cohen WM, Levinthal DA. Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly. 1990;35(1):128–52.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
69. 69. Acemoglu D, Akcigit U. Intellectual Property Rights Policy, Competition And Innovation. Journal of the European Economic Association. 2012;10(1):1–42.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
70. 70. Akcigit U, Hanley D, Serrano-Velarde N. Back to basics: Basic research spillovers, innovation policy, and growth. The Review of Economic Studies. 2021;88(1):1–43.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
71. 71. Cassiman B, Veugelers R. R&D cooperation and spillovers: some empirical evidence from Belgium. American Economic Review. 2002;92(4):1169–84.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
72. 72. Lin Z, Liu S. How Do Tax Incentives Affect Firm Innovation? Empirical Evidence from the Policy of Accelerated Depreciation of Fixed Assets. Statistical Research. 2022;39(01):91–105.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
73. 73. Braunerhjelm P, Ding D, Thulin P. Labour market mobility, knowledge diffusion and innovation. European Economic Review. 2020;123(2020):103386.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
74. 74. Ganguli I, Lin J, Reynolds N. The paper trail of knowledge spillovers: evidence from patent interferences. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics. 2020;12(2):278–302.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
Citation: Li Z, Guo L, Ping Y (2024) Revolutionizing pharmaceutical innovation: Unveiling the impact of endogenous knowledge spillover in China. PLoS ONE 19(9): e0307171. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0307171
About the Authors:
Zhuolin Li
Roles: Conceptualization, Data curation, Formal analysis, Methodology, Software, Validation, Visualization, Writing – original draft
E-mail: [email protected] (ZL); [email protected] (LG)
Affiliation: College of Economics and Management, Shanghai Ocean University, Shanghai, China
ORICD: https://orcid.org/0009-0007-3018-0566
Lin Guo
Roles: Project administration, Resources, Software, Supervision, Validation
E-mail: [email protected] (ZL); [email protected] (LG)
Affiliation: College of Economics and Management, Shanghai Ocean University, Shanghai, China
ORICD: https://orcid.org/0009-0007-4276-5481
Ying Ping
Roles: Conceptualization, Funding acquisition, Investigation, Project administration, Resources, Supervision, Writing – review & editing
Affiliation: College of Economics and Management, Shanghai Ocean University, Shanghai, China
[/RAW_REF_TEXT]
[/RAW_REF_TEXT]
[/RAW_REF_TEXT]
[/RAW_REF_TEXT]
[/RAW_REF_TEXT]
[/RAW_REF_TEXT]
1. Huang X. The pharmaceutical industry has leapt to the high end of the value chain. The State Council of the People’s Republic of China: Economic Daily; 2023 Dec. 14 [cited 2024 Jan. 30]. Available from: https://www.gov.cn/govweb/yaowen/liebiao/202312/content_6920238.htm.
2. Institute CMIIR, Market M. 2023 China Biopharmaceutical Industry Report. place unknown: publisher unknown; 2023 [cited 2023 Dec. 30]. Available from: https://file.vogel.com.cn/126/upload/resources/file/396704.pdf.
3. Ji J. From market chaos to innovation going global, how has China’s medical industry developed in the past 30 years? www.thepaper.cn: ThePaper; 2023 [cited 2024 Jan. 30]. Available from: https://www.thepaper.cn/newsDetail_forward_24999430.
4. Institute PIR. Analysis of the market size and development trend of China’s generic drug industry in 2021, and national policies to promote the high-quality development of the industry. place unknown: bg.qianzhan.com; 2022 [cited 2024 Jan. 30]. Available from: https://bg.qianzhan.com/report/detail/300/220328-ac2bb13f.html.
5. Adelheid H, Bettina P, Christian R. Local knowledge spillovers and innovation persistence of firms. Economics of Innovation and New Technology. 2023;32(6):826–50.
6. Czarnitzki D, Kraft K. Spillovers of innovation activities and their profitability. Oxford Economic Papers. 2012;64(2):302–22.
7. Thornton RA, Thompson P. Learning from experience and learning from others: An exploration of learning and spillovers in wartime shipbuilding. American Economic Review. 2001;91(5):1350–68.
8. Tseng C-Y, Pai D-C. Knowledge search, spillover and creation capability in India’s pharmaceutical industry. Technology Analysis & Strategic Management. 2014;26(2):207–22.
9. L E, B E, J A. The Impact of Knowledge Management and Knowledge Transfer in Growth and Innovation A Study of Business Start-Ups, Business Incubators and Business Accelerators. IFAC PapersOnLine. 2022;55(39):54–9.
10. Tzabbar D, Lee J, Seo D. Collaborative structure and post-mobility knowledge spillovers: A dyadic approach. Strategic Management Journal. 2022;43(9):1728–62.
11. Zacchia P. Knowledge spillovers through networks of scientists. The Review of Economic Studies. 2020;87(4):1989–2018.
12. Fershtman C, Gandal N. Direct and indirect knowledge spillovers: the “social network” of open‐source projects. The RAND Journal of Economics. 2011;42(1):70–91.
13. Coe DT, Helpman E, Hoffmaister AW. International R&D spillovers and institutions. European Economic Review. 2009;53(7):723–41.
14. Lucas RE Jr. On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics. 1988;22(1):3–42.
15. Lucas RE Jr. Ideas and growth. Economica. 2009;76(301):1–19.
16. Romer PM. Endogenous technological change. Journal of political Economy. 1990;98(5, Part 2):S71–S102.
17. Arrow KJ. The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing. The Review of Economic Studies. 1962;29(3):155–73.
18. Marshall A. The Substance of Economics. In: Marshall A, editor. Principles of Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan UK; 2013. p. 12–23.
19. Romer PM. Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth. Journal of Political Economy. 1986;94(5):1002–37.
20. Jacobs J. The economy of cities: Vintage; 2016.
21. Porter ME. Clusters and the new economics of competition. Harv Bus Rev. 1998;76(6):77–90. pmid:10187248
22. Borjas GJ, Doran KB. Which peers matter? The relative impacts of collaborators, colleagues, and competitors. Review of economics and statistics. 2015;97(5):1104–17.
23. Arvanitis S, Seliger F, Woerter M. Knowledge spillovers, competition and innovation success. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics. 2020;82(5):1017–41.
24. Audretsch DB, Belitski M. The knowledge spillover of innovation. Industrial and Corporate Change. 2022;31(6):1329–57.
25. Sawada N. Technology gap matters on spillover. Review of Development Economics. 2010;14(1):103–20.
26. Bryan KA, Lemus J, Marshall G. R&D Competition and the Direction of Innovation. International Journal of Industrial Organization. 2022;82(2022):102841.
27. Gersbach H, Schmutzler A. Endogenous technological spillovers: causes and consequences. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy. 2003;12(2):179–205.
28. Shen B. The Influence of Endogenous Knowledge Spillovers on Open Innovation Cooperation Modes Selection. Wireless Personal Communications. 2018;102(4):2701–13.
29. Arque-Castells P, Spulber DF. Measuring the private and social returns to R&D: Unintended spillovers versus technology markets. Journal of Political Economy. 2022;130(7):1860–918.
30. Spulber DF. How do competitive pressures affect incentives to innovate when there is a market for inventions? Journal of Political Economy. 2013;121(6):1007–54.
31. Bloom N, Schankerman M, Van Reenen J. Identifying technology spillovers and product market rivalry. Econometrica. 2013;81(4):1347–93.
32. Spence M. Cost Reduction, Competition, and Industry Performance. Econometrica. 1984;52(1):101–21.
33. Klein MA. Secrecy, the patent puzzle and endogenous growth. European Economic Review. 2020;126:103445.
34. Loury GC. Market structure and innovation. The quarterly journal of economics. 1979:395–410.
35. Crepon B, Duguet E. Research and development, competition and innovation pseudo-maximum likelihood and simulated maximum likelihood methods applied to count data models with heterogeneity. Journal of econometrics. 1997;79(2):355–78.
36. Bessen J, Maskin E. Sequential innovation, patents, and imitation. The RAND Journal of Economics. 2009;40(4):611–35.
37. Grabowski H. Patents, Innovation and Access to New Pharmaceuticals. Journal of International Economic Law. 2002;5(4):849–60.
38. Macho‐Stadler I, Matsushima N, Shinohara R. Organizational structure and technological investment. The Journal of Industrial Economics. 2021;69(4):785–816.
39. Galasso A, Schankerman M. Patents and cumulative innovation: Causal evidence from the courts. The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 2015;130(1):317–69.
40. Kong L, Li Q, Kaitin KI, Shao L. Innovation in the Chinese pharmaceutical industry. Nature Reviews Drug Discovery. 2023;22(1):12–3. pmid:36303035
41. Trajtenberg M. A penny for your quotes: patent citations and the value of innovations. The RAND Journal of Economics. 1990;21(1):172–87.
42. Hall BH. The manufacturing sector master file: 1959–1987. National Bureau of Economic Research Cambridge, Mass., USA; 1990 May 1990.
43. Pang R, Tu X, Yan X. How do product market competition and knowledge spillover affect enterprise R&D? An empirical identification based on multi-dimensional proximity. Industrial Economics Research. 2021(02):1–14+29.
44. Jaffe AB. Technological opportunity and spillovers of R&D: evidence from firms’ patents, profits and market value. national bureau of economic research Cambridge, Mass., USA; 1986.
45. Lucking B, Bloom N, Van Reenen J. Have R&D spillovers changed?: National Bureau of Economic Research; 2018.
46. Levinsohn J, Petrin A. Estimating Production Functions Using Inputs to Control for Unobservables. The Review of Economic Studies. 2003;70(2):317–41.
47. Aghion P, Bloom N, Blundell R, Griffith R, Howitt P. Competition and innovation: An inverted-U relationship. The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 2005;120(2):701–28.
48. Trajtenberg M, Henderson R, Jaffe A. University versus corporate patents: A window on the basicness of invention. Economics of Innovation and New Technology. 1997;5(1):19–50.
49. China NBoSo. Statistical classification of micro, small, medium and large enterprises www.stats.gov.cn: National Bureau of Statistics of China; 2018 Jan. 03 [cited 2024 Jan. 30 2024 Jan. 30]. Available from: https://www.stats.gov.cn/sj/tjbz/gjtjbz/202302/t20230213_1902763.html.
50. Cohn JB, Liu Z, Wardlaw MI. Count (and count-like) data in finance. Journal of Financial Economics. 2022;146(2):529–51.
51. Correia S, Guimarães P, Zylkin T. Fast Poisson estimation with high-dimensional fixed effects. The Stata Journal. 2020;20(1):95–115.
52. Correia S. Singletons, cluster-robust standard errors and fixed effects: A bad mix. Technical Note, Duke University. 2015;7.
53. Griliches Z. Issues in assessing the contribution of research and development to productivity growth. The Bell Journal of Economics. 1979;10(1):92–116.
54. Licheng Y, Zheng Z, Yunyun Z. Knowledge Spillover and Green Innovation: Moderating Effect of Institutional Pressure and Absorptive Capacity. Soft Science. 2023;37(09):67–77.
55. Wooldridge JM. Control function methods in applied econometrics. Journal of Human Resources. 2015;50(2):420–45.
56. Kaplan SN, Zingales L. Do Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities Provide Useful Measures of Financing Constraints?*. The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1997;112(1):169–215.
57. Arqué‐Castells P, Mohnen P. Sunk costs, extensive R&D subsidies and permanent inducement effects. The Journal of Industrial Economics. 2015;63(3):458–94.
58. Lach S. Do R&D subsidies stimulate or displace private R&D? Evidence from Israel. The journal of industrial economics. 2002;50(4):369–90.
59. BROWN JR, FAZZARI SM, PETERSEN BC. Financing Innovation and Growth: Cash Flow, External Equity, and the 1990s R&D Boom. The Journal of Finance. 2009;64(1):151–85.
60. Thompson P, Fox-Kean M. Patent citations and the geography of knowledge spillovers: A reassessment. American Economic Review. 2005;95(1):450–60.
61. Belenzon S, Schankerman M. Spreading the word: Geography, policy, and knowledge spillovers. Review of Economics and Statistics. 2013;95(3):884–903.
62. Li YA. Borders and distance in knowledge spillovers: Dying over time or dying with age?—Evidence from patent citations. European Economic Review. 2014;71:152–72.
63. Murata Y, Nakajima R, Okamoto R, Tamura R. Localized knowledge spillovers and patent citations: A distance-based approach. Review of Economics and Statistics. 2014;96(5):967–85.
64. Schnitzer M, Watzinger M. Measuring the Spillovers of Venture Capital. Review of Economics and Statistics. 2022;104(2):276–92.
65. Zhu P, Xiang G, Wang Y. R&D Spill-over Effects: Evidence from Chinese Industrial Sectors. Economic Research Journal. 2016;51(11):44–55.
66. Kaufman RL. Interaction effects in linear and generalized linear models: examples and applications using Stata: SAGE Publications, Inc.; 2019.
67. Aguiar L, Gagnepain P. Absorptive capacity, knowledge spillovers and incentive contracts. International Journal of Industrial Organization. 2022;82:102830.
68. Cohen WM, Levinthal DA. Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly. 1990;35(1):128–52.
69. Acemoglu D, Akcigit U. Intellectual Property Rights Policy, Competition And Innovation. Journal of the European Economic Association. 2012;10(1):1–42.
70. Akcigit U, Hanley D, Serrano-Velarde N. Back to basics: Basic research spillovers, innovation policy, and growth. The Review of Economic Studies. 2021;88(1):1–43.
71. Cassiman B, Veugelers R. R&D cooperation and spillovers: some empirical evidence from Belgium. American Economic Review. 2002;92(4):1169–84.
72. Lin Z, Liu S. How Do Tax Incentives Affect Firm Innovation? Empirical Evidence from the Policy of Accelerated Depreciation of Fixed Assets. Statistical Research. 2022;39(01):91–105.
73. Braunerhjelm P, Ding D, Thulin P. Labour market mobility, knowledge diffusion and innovation. European Economic Review. 2020;123(2020):103386.
74. Ganguli I, Lin J, Reynolds N. The paper trail of knowledge spillovers: evidence from patent interferences. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics. 2020;12(2):278–302.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer
© 2024 Li et al. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License: http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ (the “License”), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited. Notwithstanding the ProQuest Terms and Conditions, you may use this content in accordance with the terms of the License.
Abstract
Modern medical technology innovation is a critical safeguard for human health, while a significant number of developing nations are confronted with the challenge of biopharmaceutical technological advancement. To investigate the possible routes of technological advancement, we investigated the impact of the endogenous knowledge spillover effect on firm innovation endeavors. Our research involves a theoretical two-stage R&D game model that is built around the characteristics of pharmaceutical organizations. Theoretical studies elucidated the impact as well as the probable mechanism of the spillover effect. To verify the theoretical study, we conducted econometric analysis using data from the pharmaceutical sector of Chinese enterprise listed on the A-share market. The study’s findings indicate that endogenous knowledge spillovers impede organizations’ innovation endeavors. This phenomenon may be attributed to the existence of the patent race paradigm and high concentration of enterprises’ R&D endeavors in specific areas. Additional examination of heterogeneity demonstrates that private firms, small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs), and non-high-tech enterprises experience a larger adverse impact from the spillover effect. Hence, we suggest implementing "loser’s subsidies", reallocating R&D resources, and making modifications to competition policies as measures to enhance the innovation performance of biopharmaceutical markets. These policies will facilitate the technical advancement of medicines in developing nations.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer