Introduction
Knowledge is recognized as critical organizational resource. Knowledge management refers to the entire process from knowledge creation and knowledge sharing to knowledge utilization [1]. Through effective knowledge management, an organization can enhance innovative capability and acquire sustainable competitive advantage [1]. Knowledge sharing, a vital component of the knowledge management process, refers to the exchange of knowledge among organizational employees with the aim of collectively solving work-related problems and improving overall organizational performance. [2]. The integration of digital technologies in organizational processes has transformed knowledge sharing practices from offline to online [3–5]. Online knowledge sharing refers to the practice of exchanging knowledge, expertise, and information through digital platforms, making it possible for employees to engage in collaborative efforts, irrespective of geographic location. Online platforms now serve as essential tools in this transformation, enabling not only remote and instant access but also fostering a more inclusive and persistent knowledge-sharing ecosystem. [6,7]. Online knowledge-sharing communities rely heavily on the voluntary and effortful contributions of employees. The content generated within these communities is often grounded in employees’ expert knowledge and firsthand experience, making it a valuable asset for both individual and organizational growth [8,9]. However, the sustainability of content generation in these communities is largely contingent upon the motivation of contributors. To encourage ongoing participation, organizations increasingly turn to incentive mechanisms, particularly monetary rewards [10,11]. Previous research differentiate rewards into two categories: peer-based, where individuals incentivize peers at personal cost [12], and institutional, where organizations systematically reward contributors [13]. Current research largely presumes that reward policies are static, with the intensity of incentives remaining unchanged despite evolving community dynamics. Although monetary rewards serve as a powerful extrinsic motivator, their effectiveness is highly sensitive to strategic design and adaptive implementation. Poorly structured reward systems may lead to unintended consequences, such as a focus on short-term contributions rather than long-term engagement [14], or a decrease in intrinsic motivation to share knowledge [15]. To address these limitations, our study proposes an open-loop optimal control framework that designs predefined reward policies balancing organizational costs with long-term engagement.
Motivation
Consider the situation where an organizational employee (she, for short) holds some kind of valuable knowledge (new skills, new methods, etc.) from the sharing of which other organizational employees as well as the organization itself could benefit (the employees’ job performance could be enhanced significantly, the organizational expected performance could be attained, etc.). From organizational standpoint, the sharing of the knowledge is encouraged. But from individual standpoint, the employee faces the choice of sharing her knowledge or withholding her knowledge. This situation is referred to as the knowledge-sharing dilemma [16–18]. In this situation, the employee has to carefully trade the benefits of sharing her knowledge (gaining expert status, receiving public praise, etc.) against the cost of doing so (time cost for organizing documents about her knowledge, risk of exposing her competitive edge, risk of being terminated). She only prefers to sharing her knowledge if the estimated total benefit exceeds the estimated total cost. Otherwise, she would choose to withhold her knowledge.
Participants in online knowledge sharing are categorized as lurkers (i.e., those who read posts without making any contribution) and posters (i.e., those who share knowledge through posting) [19,20]. Reportedly, the majority of participants (exceeding 90%) are lurkers [21]. In order to survive and succeed in fierce market competition, organizations should take a variety of measures, ranging from training self-efficacy to bestowing rewards, to motivate their employees’ knowledge sharing intentions [8,9,22].
Among all possible knowledge-sharing promotion mechanisms, awarding monetary rewards may possibly be the most direct promotion mechanism. As far as we are concerned, there has been no report in literature on systematic research of monetary reward mechanism for promoting knowledge sharing. Under the time continuity assumption of the rewards, the present paper addresses the issue. We refer to the function of reward increase rates for all organizational employees at all time points as a knowledge-sharing promotion (KSP) policy. In practice, there exist numerous feasible KSP policies, and different KSP policies lead to different cost benefits. Consequently, it is of practical importance to consider the following problem:
knowledge-sharing promotion (KSP) problem: Under the monetary reward mechanism for promoting online knowledge sharing, find a cost-effective KSP policy among all feasible KSP policies.
As far as we are concerned, there is no report in literature on the problem. This paper is devoted to addressing the problem through mathematical modeling.
Contributions
In this paper the following contributions are made.
* First, we explicitly formulate the KSP problem for the first time. Second, we introduce a mathematical model for characterizing the evolution of state of the knowledge-sharing community. Finally, we model the KSP problem as an optimal control problem (the KSP model).
* First, applying optimal control theory to the KSP model, we give a numerical algorithm for solving the KSP model. Second, we corroborate the feasibility of the algorithm through extensive experiments.
* First, we inspect the applicability of the algorithm by giving estimation/approximation schemes for the relevant parameters/functions. Second, we examine the influence of these factors on the performance of the algorithm.
This paper pioneers the application of optimal control theory in the research of knowledge sharing. The subsequent materials are organized in this fashion: The related work section reviews the related work. The mathematical modeling of the KSP problem section and the solution of the KSP model section establish and solve the KSP model, respectively. The further discussions section makes further discussions. This work is summarized by the concluding remarks section.
Related work
This section reviews the related work and highlights the innovations of the present paper.
Knowledge sharing promotion mechanism
The social dilemma of knowledge sharing renders most organizational employees to withhold their valuable knowledge (see Subsection I-A). This condition seriously weakens organizational competitive advantage. For the purpose of promoting knowledge sharing, much efforts have been put on investigating the influence of various factors, ranging from intrinsic factors such as self-efficacy and enjoyment to extrinsic factors such as rewards and reciprocity, on knowledge sharing behavior [23–26]. Previous studies have predominantly focused on posters because of their direct contributions to knowledge sharing [27]. In particular, it was empirically found that external incentives, such as rewards and recognition, are pivotal in motivating posters to contribute actively [28,29]. In recent years, the function of lurkers in knowledge sharing has received considerable interest [8,9,22].
The promotion mechanism for knowledge sharing has been explored extensively. For instance, [16] proposed three feasible approaches to promoting knowledge sharing: reconstructing the pay-off function, increasing efficacy, and promoting group identity and personal responsibility. Selectively rewarding individual contributions in the form of monetary reward or social recognition or collective gains is viewed as an effective means of reconstructing the pay-off function. Establishing a feedback mechanism of using shared knowledge is regarded as a feasible technique of increasing efficacy. Establishing knowledge-sharing community is recognized as an applicable way of promoting group identity. As another example, [18] suggested to improve organizational knowledge-sharing culture by changing the performance climate. [30,31] investigated the cost-effectiveness of institutional incentives for promoting cooperation and proposed mathematical optimization models for reward and punishment mechanisms in the evolution of group cooperation. Building on this foundation, this paper further extends the application scenarios of incentive mechanisms by focusing on the design of dynamic incentive strategies in the process of organizational online knowledge sharing.
To our knowledge, all previous explorations on knowledge sharing promotion mechanism were conducted on a qualitative basis as opposed to a quantitative basis.
Applications of optimal control theory
Optimal control theory is devoted to finding an optimal control strategy for a dynamic system [32]. In the past decades, optimal control theory has witnessed widespread applications in diverse areas, ranging from containment of malware propagation [33,34] and suppression of rumor spreading [35,36] to defense against advanced cyberattacks [37,38] and development of advertising policy [39,40]. [41,42] explored the incentive strategies in evolutionary cooperation optimization, especially using optimal control theory to optimize incentive strategies to minimize costs when using positive and negative incentives to achieve the target state. Our research extends this framework to the context of online community knowledge sharing, and is dedicated to finding personalized and optimal incentive strategies for different individuals. In particular, [43] is closely related to the present paper. In this paper, the product co-creation problem was resolved through optimal control approach. Here, valuable suggestions about a new product are shared in the company-sponsored online community, somewhat like the situation where valuable knowledge are shared in the online knowledge-sharing community.
As far as we are concerned, there is no report in literature on the application control theory to the research of knowledge sharing.
Innovations of this work
The innovations of this work are threefold. First, the problem of promoting knowledge sharing through monetary reward (the KSP problem) is proposed. The problem is of practical importance, because its solution helps promote knowledge sharing. Second, by characterizing the evolution of state of the knowledge-sharing community over time, the KSP problem is modeled successfully as an optimal control problem (the KSP model). Finally, the KSP model is resolved successfully.
Mathematical modeling of the KSP problem
This section is devoted to the mathematical modeling of the KSP problem. First, a KSP policy is formulated mathematically. Second, the evolutionary process of state of the knowledge-sharing community is characterized by a dynamic model. Finally, the KSP problem is modeled mathematically.
KSP policy
Consider the KSP problem. Suppose the organization intends to create and maintain an online community for facilitating the sharing of knowledge among its employees. We refer to the community as the knowledge-sharing (KS) community held by the organization. Suppose the community accommodates all organizational employees (numbered 1 through N) as members, each member is encouraged to create posts in the community to share new knowledge, and each member has access to all posts retained in the community.
Suppose the organization intends to promote knowledge sharing through monetary rewards in the time horizon [ 0 , T ] . Here, t = 0 stands for the time at which the KS community is created. T is termed the knowledge-sharing promotion period. For all i and t, let denote the increase rate of the amount of money given to the i-th employee at time t for exciting her to share her knowledge, which is termed the i-th reward increase rate at time t. Furthermore, the function
(1)
is termed a knowledge-sharing promotion (KSP) policy. In what follows, the KSP policy is abbreviated as x.
Skilled employees have rich knowledge. If a skilled employee share her knowledge in the KS community, those employees who acquire the knowledge could significantly enhance their respective job performance. For the purpose of making up a cost-effective KSP policy, the value of the knowledge shared by each employee needs to be estimated based on his historical job performance. On this basis and in view of the limited reward budget, the maximum possible reward increase rate for each employee at any time is determined. Let denote the maximum possible reward increase rate for the i-th employee at any time. Let , which is termed the maximum reward increase rate over the KS community. On the other hand, since piecewise continuous functions cover all practically useful functions, in what follows it is reasonably assumed that all KSP policies are piecewise continuous. In summary, we assume the set of feasible KSP policies is
(2)
where PC [ 0 , T ] stands for the set of piecewise continuous functions on the interval [ 0 , T ] .
Under the KSP policy x, the total amount of money paid to all organizational employees equals
(3)
Eq (3) represents the total cost of monetary rewards provided by the organization to all employees over the time horizon . Here, the summation accounts for the reward increase rates of all employees at the time t, and the total cost is the cumulative sum of these rates over the the entire time horizon [ 0 , T ] . This formulation is based on the assumptions that rewards are distributed continuously over time and that the reward increase rates are piecewise continuous functions.
State of the KS community and its evolution
We refer to an employee as posting at a given time if she is creating a post used for sharing her knowledge at the time. Otherwise, we refer to the employee as lurking at the time. For all i and t, let (resp. ) denote the probability of the i-th employee being posting (resp. lurking) at time t. Then, . The vector
(4)
is termed the state of the KS community at time t. Since the initial states of all employees can be observed based on their prior participation performance, we have .
The state of the KS community varies over time. To capture the evolution of state of the KS community over time, introduce a collection of notations and assumptions.
First, owing to the exciting effect of monetary reward, each lurker may possibly become posting at any time. In what follows it is reasonably assumed that, owing to the the exciting effect of monetary reward, the i-th employee becomes posting from lurking at time t at rate . Here, f ( 0 ) = 0, f is increasing and flattens out (the exciting effect of monetary reward slows down). In what follows, f is termed the reward influence function.
Second, owing to the exciting effect of posters, each lurker may potentially become a poster at any time. In what follows it is reasonably assumed that, owing to the exciting effect of posters, the i-th employee becomes posting from lurking at time t at rate . Here, g ( 0 ) = 0, the function g is increasing and flattens out (the exciting effect of posters slows down). The term captures peer influence: the summed posting probabilities represent community-wide activity, which incentivizes lurkers to participate. The function g increasing yet saturating, reflects diminishing marginal returns of group engagement. In what follows, g is termed the poster influence function. For ease in mathematical treatment, in what follows assume g is differential.
Finally, owing to a variety of reasons (busyness with work, rest, etc.), each employee becomes lurking from posting at any time at the constant positive rate α, which is termed the lurking rate.
In summary, under the KSP policy x the state of the KS community evolves following the differential system
(5)
The system is termed the evolutionary model for the state of the KS community. See Fig 1 for an illustration of the model.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Optimal control modeling of the KSP problem
Every poster can bring benefit to the organization. For i = 1 , ⋯ , N, let denote the benefit per unit time generated by the i-th employee if she is posting. Let . In what follows it is reasonably assumed that ω is linearly proportional to , i.e., , where c is a positive constant, which is termed the reward-return coefficient. Under the KSP policy x, the overall benefit gained by the organization is estimated to be
(6)
In view of the cost needed for executing the KSP policy x (see Eq (2)), the cost benefit of executing the KSP policy x is estimated to be
(7)
Therefore, the KSP problem can be modeled as the optimal control problem
(8)
We refer to the optimal control problem as the KSP model.
Each instance of the KSP model (8) is represented by the 8-tuple
(9)
For convenience, in what follows each instance of the KSP model is termed a KSP instance.
A solution of the KSP model
This section is committed to solving the KSP model established in the preceding section.
An algorithm for solving the KSP model
The Hamiltonian function for the KSP model (8) reads
(10)
Here, stands for the adjoint.
Suppose x is an optimal control for the KSP model (8). Let P be the solution to the corresponding state evolutionary model (5). Pontryagin Maximum Principle [32] tells us that there exists an adjoint function λ such that λ ( T ) = 0 and
(11)
Direct calculations lead to
(12)
Again by Pontryagin Maximum Principle [32], we get that
(13)
Simple algebra leads to
(14)
By combining the system (5), the system (12), and the system (14), we get the optimality system for the KSP problem, which is shown in the system (15). In what follows, the optimality system is viewed as a system in the KSP polocy x, whereas the state function P and the adjoint function λ are viewed as auxiliary functions.
(15)
By applying the Forward-Backward Sweep Method [44] to the optimality system (15), we get a numerical algorithm for solving the KSP model (8), which we refer to as the KSP algorithm. See Algorithm 1 for a pseudo-code description of the algorithm. The basic idea for the KSP Algorithm is to generate a sequence of feasible KSP policies by iteratively solving the optimality system (15) until the generated sequence converges. Then, the KSP algorithm outputs the finally generated KSP policy.
Algorithm 1: KSP
Input: KSP instance ,convergence error ϵ.
Output: KSP policy x.
1: k ← 0; ;
2: repeat
3: k ← k + 1;
4: calculate the state function P using the system (5) with ;
5: ;
6: calculate the adjoint function λ using the system (12) with and ;
7: ;
8: calculate the KSP policy x using the system (14) with , and ;
9: ;
10: until ; return .
Feasibility of the KSP algorithm
We refer to the KSP algorithm as feasible if (i) the algorithm converges, i.e., the sequence of KSP policies generated by the KSP algorithm converges, and (ii) the algorithm is satisfactory, i.e., the KSP policy returned by the KSP algorithm beats the majority of other feasible KSP policies (in terms of the cost benefit). Now, validate the feasibility of the KSP algorithm through numerical experiments.
Experiment 1. Consider the KSP instance
Here, N = 100, T = 3, is a vector generated randomly in the region , f ( z ) = 0 . 3tanh ( z ) , g ( z ) = 0 . 2ln ( 1 + z ) , α = 0 . 1, c = 10, and is a vector generated randomly within the interval [ 0 , 0 . 5 ] .
1. 1) Running the KSP algorithm on , it is observed that the generated sequence of KSP policies converges. Let denote the finally generated KSP policy. See Fig 2(a) for partial display of (the full data is available in Supporting information).
2. 2) Generate a set of 100 feasible KSP policies randomly and uniformly, denoted . Fig 2(b) exhibits J(x), (the full data is available in Supporting information). It is observed that , x ∈ S. Hence, is satisfactory.
Experiment 2. Consider the KSP instance
Here, N = 300, T = 4, is a vector generated randomly in the region , f ( z ) = 0 . 4tanh ( z ) , g ( z ) = 0 . 1ln ( 1 + z ) , α = 0 . 05, c = 5, and is a vector generated randomly within the interval [ 0 , 0 . 5 ] .
1. 1) Running the KSP algorithm on , it is observed that the generated sequence of KSP policies converges. Let denote the finally generated KSP policy. See Fig 3(a) for partial exhibition of (the full data is available in Supporting information).
2. 2) Generate a set of 100 feasible KSP policies randomly and uniformly, denoted . Fig 3(b) demonstrates J(x), (the full data is available in Supporting information). It is observed that , x ∈ S. Hence, is satisfactory.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
After leveraging the KSP algorithm, we get: (a) the KSP policy , (b) expected employee state evolution over time, (c) J(x), .
Experiment 3. Consider the KSP instance
Here, N = 500, T = 5, is a vector generated randomly in the region , f ( z ) = 0 . 3tanh ( z ) , g ( z ) = 0 . 2ln ( 1 + z ) , α = 0 . 1, c = 10, and is a vector generated randomly within the interval [ 0 , 0 . 5 ] .
1. 1) Running the KSP algorithm on , it is observed that the generated sequence of KSP policies converges. Let denote the finally generated KSP policy. See Fig 4(a) for partial demonstration of (the full data is available in Supporting information).
2. 2) Generate a set of 100 feasible KSP policies randomly and uniformly, denoted . Fig 4(b) demonstrates J(x), (the full data is available in Supporting information). It is observed that , x ∈ S. Hence, is satisfactory.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
After executing the KSP algorithm, we obtain: (a) the KSP policy , (b) expected employee state evolution over time, (c) J(x), .
Based on 1000 similar experiments, we conclude that (i) the generated sequence of KSP policies converges and (ii) the finally generated KSP policy is satisfactory in terms of the cost benefit. As thus, we conclude that the KSP algorithm is feasible. Therefore, we recommend the KSP algorithm.
The computational efficiency of the KSP algorithm primarily depends on the number of employees N, Our experiments demonstrate that the algorithm converges efficiently for moderate-sized problems(e.g., N = 100 , 300 , 500 and T = 3 , 4 , 5). However, for very large N, the computational cost may increase significantly due to the larger system size. The algorithm requires solving a set of differential equations for each employee. As N increases, the size of the system also increases, leading to higher computational complexity. This is particularly evident in the state evolutionary model (Eq 5) and the adjoint system (Eq 12), both of which involve N equation. Additionally, in rare scenarios (e.g., initial guesses far from the optimal solution, highly nonlinear reward or poster influence functions), the algorithm may require more iterations or parameter adjustments to ensure convergence.
Further discussions
In the preceding section, the KSP algorithm was proposed and its feasibility was corroborated. This section addresses some issues related to the KSP algorithm. First, the applicability of the KSP algorithm is inspected. Second, the influence of some factors is examined.
Applicability of the KSP algorithm
First, consider the applicability of the KSP algorithm. There are seven factors involved in the KSP instance (9): the number of organizational employees, N, the knowledge-sharing promotion period, T, the maximum reward increase rate, , the reward influence function, f, the poster influence function, g, the lurking rate, α, and the reward-return coefficient. Before the KSP algorithm can be applied to a real-world scenario, all the seven relevant factors need to be determined or estimated or approximated.
The number of organizational employees is already known. The knowledge-sharing promotion period is determined by the demand on knowledge sharing. The maximum reward increase rate is determined by the scheduled reward budget as well as each employee’s historical job performance. The lurking rate and the reward-return coefficient are estimated by the organization through collecting and processing relevant historical data. The reward influence function and the poster influence function are approximated by the organization through collecting and fitting relevant historical data. Once all the factors involved in the KSP instance are determined, the KSP algorithm can be applied to the KSP instance to generate a cost-effective KSP policy.
Influence of some factors
First, inspect the influence of some factors on the performance of the KSP algorithm. First, examine the influence of the number of employees.
Experiment 4. Let N = { 10 , 20 , ⋯ , 100 } . Consider the KSP instances
For N ∈ N, let denote the KSP policy generated by running the KSP algorithm on . Fig 5 displays , N ∈ N. It is observed that is increasing with the increasing N.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
This figure exhibits versus N, N ∈ N.
Based on 100 similar experiments, we conclude that the performance of the KSP algorithm is increasing with the increasing number of employees. This conclusion implies that the recommended KSP policy is especially suited to large-sized organizations.
second, examine the influence of the knowledge-sharing promotion period.
Experiment 5. Let T = { 1 , 2 , ⋯ , 10 } . Consider the KSP instances
For T ∈ T, let denote the KSP policy generated by running the KSP algorithm on . Fig 6 exhibits , T ∈ T. It is observed that is increasing with the entended T.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
This figure shows versus T, T ∈ T.
Based on 100 similar experiments, we conclude that the performance of the KSP algorithm is increasing with the extended knowledge-sharing promotion period. In practice, it is suggested to extend the knowledge-sharing promotion period to gain higher cost benefit of knowledge sharing.
Third, consider the influence of the maximum reward increase rate.
Experiment 6. Let be a vector generated randomly in the region . Let denote ten vectors obtained by scaling such that . Let . Consider the KSP instances
For , let denote the KSP policy generated by running the KSP algorithm on . Fig 7 plots , . It is observed that is increasing with the increasing .
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
This figure demonstrates versus , .
Based on 100 similar experiments. In each of these experiments, we conclude that the performance of the KSP algorithm is increasing with the increasing maximum reward increase rate. In practice, it is suggested to properly increase the reward budget to gain higher cost benefit of knowledge sharing.
Fourth, investigate the influence of the reward influence function.
Experiment 7. Let , , ⋯ , . Let . Consider the KSP instances
For f ∈ F, let denote the KSP policy generated by running the KSP algorithm on . Fig 8 depicts , f ∈ F. It is observed that is increasing with the increasing f.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
This figure depicts versus f, f ∈ F.
Based on 100 similar experiments, we conclude that the performance of the KSP algorithm is increasing with the increasing reward influence function.
Fifth, look into the influence of the poster influence function.
Experiment 8. Let , , ⋯ , . Let . Consider the KSP instances
For g ∈ G, let denote the KSP policy generated by running the KSP algorithm on . Fig 9 portrays , g ∈ G. It is observed that is increasing with the increasing g.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
The figure demonstrates versus g, g ∈ G.
Based on 100 similar experiments, we conclude that the performance of the KSP algorithm is increasing with the increasing poster influence function.
Next, examine the influence of the lurking rate.
Experiment 9. Let A = { 0 . 05 , 0 . 06 , ⋯ , 0 . 14 } . Consider the KSP instances
For α ∈ A, let denote the KSP policy generated by running the KSP algorithm on . Fig 10 displays , α ∈ A. It is observed that is decreasing with the increasing α.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
The figure shows versus α, α ∈ A.
Based on 100 similar experiments, we conclude that the performance of the KSP algorithm is decreasing with the increasing lurking rate. In practice, it is suggested to take effective measures to stimulate lurkers.
Finally, examine the influence of the reward-return conversion coefficient.
Experiment 10. Let C = { 5 , 6 , ⋯ , 14 } . Consider the KSP instances
For c ∈ C, let denote the KSP policy generated by running the KSP algorithm on . Fig 11 demonstrates versus c, c ∈ C. It is observed that is increasing with the increasing c.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
This figure depicts versus c, c ∈ C.
Based on 100 similar experiments, we conclude that the performance of the KSP algorithm is increasing with the increasing reward-return coefficient.
In practice, the parameters α and c involved in the KSP model are roughly estimated, and the functions f and g involved in the KSP model are roughly approximated. As thus, the advantage of the KSP algorithm is questionable. Fortunately, it is observed from the above experiment results that the performance of the KSP algorithm depends continuously on the two parameters and the two functions. This observation implies that the KSP algorithm is robust to small perturbations of these factors. Consequently, the applicability of the KSP algorithm is further consolidated.
Concluding remarks
This paper has proposed a novel knowledge sharing promotion problem. The problem has been reduced to an optimal control model. The model has been resolved successfully. We believe this work helps promote knowledge sharing.
There exist some open related issues. First, in this paper the knowledge-sharing community is assumed to be fixed. Due to the fluidity of organizational employees as well as the voluntariness of knowledge sharing, the knowledge-sharing community varies over time. Hence, it is worth studying the KSP problem for time-varying knowledge-sharing community [45,46]. Second, in this paper it is assumed that the employees’ response to monetary rewards is immediate. In practice, the response always lags behind the reward. In this context, the KSP problem should be modeled as a delayed optimal control problem [47,48]. Third, recent advances in adaptive reward mechanisms [49] suggest that dynamically adjusting reward intensity based on real-time participation levels—for instance, increasing incentives when lurkers dominate and reducing rewards when posters prevail—could further optimize cost-efficiency and long-term stability. Integrating such feedback-driven mechanisms into the KSP framework represents a promising direction. Next, in practice the monetary rewards for promoting knowledge sharing can only be awarded in a sequential manner. In this context, the KSP problem should be treated through optimal impulsive control approach [50,51]. Last, owing to the knowledge-sharing dilemma, there is interest conflict between the organization and a skilled employee. As thus, the KSP problem may be addressed through game-theoretic modeling [52–54].
Supporting information
S1 Data. Full data of Experiment 1.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0320236.s001
(XLSX)
S2 Data. Full data of Experiment 2.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0320236.s002
(XLSX)
S3 Data. Full data of Experiment 3.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0320236.s003
(XLSX)
Acknowledgments
The authors are grateful to the anonymous reviewers and the editor for their helpful comments and suggestions.
References
1. 1. Dalkir K. Knowledge management in theory and practice. Routledge; 2011.
2. 2. Wang S, Noe RA. Knowledge sharing: A review and directions for future research. Hum Resour Manag Rev. 2010;20:115–31.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
3. 3. Aboelmaged MG. Knowledge sharing through enterprise social network (ESN) systems: Motivational drivers and their impact on employees’ productivity. J Knowl Manag. 2018;22(2):362–83.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
4. 4. Castaneda DI, Cuellar S. Knowledge sharing and innovation: A systematic review. Knowl Process Manag. 2020;27(3):159–73.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
5. 5. Deng H, Duan SX, Wibowo S. Digital technology driven knowledge sharing for job performance. J Knowl Manag. 2023;27(2).
* View Article
* Google Scholar
6. 6. Nguyen T-M, Malik A. Cognitive processes, rewards and online knowledge sharing behaviour: the moderating effect of organisational innovation. J Knowl Manag. 2020;24(6):1241–61.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
7. 7. Nwankpa J, Roumani Y, Datta P. Process innovation in the digital age of business: The role of digital business intensity and knowledge management. J Knowl Manag. 2022;26(5):1319–41.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
8. 8. Nguyen M, Malik A, Sharma P. How to motivate employees to engage in online knowledge sharing? Differences between posters and lurkers. J Knowl Manag. 2021;25(7):1811–31.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
9. 9. Nguyen M, Ngo LV, Gregory G. Motivation in organisational online knowledge sharing. J Knowl Manag. 2021;26(1):102–25.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
10. 10. Burtch G, Hong Y, Bapna R, Griskevicius V. Stimulating online reviews by combining financial incentives and social norms. Manag Sci. 2018;64(5):2065–82.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
11. 11. Wang J, Li G, Hui K-L. Monetary incentives and knowledge spillover: Evidence from a natural experiment. Manag Sci. 2021;68(5):3549–72.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
12. 12. Ozono H, Kamijo Y, Shimizu K. The role of peer reward and punishment for public goods problems in a localized society. Sci Rep 2020;10(1):8211. pmid:32427936
* View Article
* PubMed/NCBI
* Google Scholar
13. 13. Dong Y, Sasaki T, Zhang B. The competitive advantage of institutional reward. Proc Biol Sci 2019;286(1899):20190001. pmid:30914009
* View Article
* PubMed/NCBI
* Google Scholar
14. 14. Sun Y, Dong X, McIntyre S. Motivation of user-generated content: Social connectedness moderates the effects of monetary rewards. Market Sci. 2017;36(3):329–37.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
15. 15. Deci EL, Koestner R, Ryan RM. A meta-analytic review of experiments examining the effects of extrinsic rewards on intrinsic motivation. Psychol Bull. 1999;125(6):627–68; discussion 692–700. pmid:10589297
* View Article
* PubMed/NCBI
* Google Scholar
16. 16. Cabrera A, Cabrera EF. Knowledge-sharing dilemmas. Org Stud. 2002;23(5):687–710.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
17. 17. Al-Alawi A, Al-Marzooqi NY, Mohammed YF. Organizational culture and knowledge sharing: Critical success factors. J Knowl Manag. 2007;11(2):22–42.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
18. 18. Halisah A, Jayasingam S, Ramayah T, Popa S. Social dilemmas in knowledge sharing: An examination of the interplay between knowledge sharing culture and performance climate. J Knowl Manag. 2021;25(7):1708–25.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
19. 19. Lai HM, Chen TT. Knowledge sharing in interest online communities: A comparison of posters and lurkers. Comput Hum Behav. 2014;35:295–306.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
20. 20. Sun N, Rau PP, Ma L. Understanding lurkers in online communities: A literature review. Comput Hum Behav. 2014;38:110–7.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
21. 21. Marett K, Joshi K. The decision to share information and rumors: Examining the role of motivation in an online discussion forum. Commun Assoc Inform Syst. 2009;24(1):47–68.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
22. 22. Nguyen M, Fry M-L, Arli D. Share or not share knowledge: Posters versus lurkers in organisational online knowledge sharing and internal marketing. Aust Market J. 2024;32(2):151–61.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
23. 23. Teo TSH, Lim VKG, Lai RYC. Intrinsic and extrinsic motivation in Internet usage. Omega. 1999;27(1):25–37.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
24. 24. Wasko MM, Faraj S. ‘It is what one does’: Why people participate and help others in electronic communities of practice. J Strat Inform Syst. 2000;9(2–3):155–73.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
25. 25. Lin H-F. Effects of extrinsic and intrinsic motivation on employee knowledge sharing intentions. J Inform Sci. 2007;33(2):135–49.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
26. 26. Nguyen T-M, Nham TP, Froese FJ, Malik A. Motivation and knowledge sharing: A meta-analysis of main and moderating effects. J Knowl Manag. 2019;23(5):998–1016.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
27. 27. Chen IYL, Chen N-S, Kinshuk . Examining the factors influencing participants’ knowledge sharing behavior in virtual learning communities. Educ Technol Soc. 2009;12(1):134–48.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
28. 28. Bock G-W, Zmud R, Kim Y-G, Lee J-N. Behavioral intention formation in knowledge sharing: Examining the roles of extrinsic motivators, social-psychological forces, and organizational climate. MIS Q. 2005;29(1):87–111.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
29. 29. Tohidinia Z, Mosakhani M. Knowledge sharing behavior and its predictors. Ind Manag Data Syst. 2010;110(4);611–631.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
30. 30. Duong MH, Han TA. Cost efficiency of institutional incentives for promoting cooperation in finite populations. Proc Math Phys Eng Sci 2021;477(2254):20210568. pmid:35153590
* View Article
* PubMed/NCBI
* Google Scholar
31. 31. Han TA, Tran-Thanh L. Cost-effective external interference for promoting the evolution of cooperation. Sci Rep 2018;8(1):15997. pmid:30375463
* View Article
* PubMed/NCBI
* Google Scholar
32. 32. Kirk DE. Optimal control theory: An introduction. Dover Publications. 2004.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
33. 33. Eshghi S, Khouzani MHR, Sarkar S, Venkatesh SS. Optimal patching in clustered malware epidemics. IEEE/ACM Trans Netw. 2016;24(1):283–98.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
34. 34. Huang K, Li P, Yang LX, Yang X, Tang YY. Seeking best-balanced patch-injecting strategies through optimal control approach. Secur Commun Netw. 2019;2019:2315627.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
35. 35. Huang DW, Yang LX, Li P, Yang X, Tang YY. Developing cost-effective rumor-refuting strategy through game-theoretic approach. IEEE Syst J. 2021;15(4):5034–45.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
36. 36. Huang K, Yang X, Yang LX, Zhu Y, Li G. Mitigating the impact of a false message through sequential release of clarifying messages. IEEE Trans Netw Sci Eng. 2024;11(2):1785–98.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
37. 37. Yang L, Li P, Yang X, Xiang Y, Jiang F, Zhou W. Effective quarantine and recovery scheme against advanced persistent threat. IEEE Trans Syst Man Cybern: Syst. 2021;51(10):5977–91.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
38. 38. Sun H, Yang X, Yang LX, Huang K, Li G. Impulsive artificial defense against advanced persistent threat. IEEE Trans Inform Foren Sec. 2023;18:3506–16.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
39. 39. Huang K, Yang LX, Yang X, Tang YY. Effective multiplatform advertising policy. IEEE Trans Syst Man Cybern: Syst. 2022;52(7):4483–93.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
40. 40. Danaher PJ. Optimal microtargeting of advertising. J Market Res. 2023;60(3):564–86.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
41. 41. Wang S, Liu L, Chen X. Incentive strategies for the evolution of cooperation: Analysis and optimization. Europhys Lett. 2021:136(6);68002.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
42. 42. Wang S, Chen X, Xiao Z, Szolnoki A, Vasconcelos VV. Optimization of institutional incentives for cooperation in structured populations. J R Soc Interface 2023;20(199):20220653. pmid:36722070
* View Article
* PubMed/NCBI
* Google Scholar
43. 43. Hu J, Yang LX, Yang X, Huang K, Li G, Xiang Y. Cost-effective company response policy for product co-creation in company-sponsored online community. IEEE Trans Syst Man Cybern: Syst. 2024;54(7):4494–506.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
44. 44. McAsey M, Mou L, Han W. Convergence of the forward-backward sweep method in optimal control. Comput Optim Appl. 2012;53(1):207–26.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
45. 45. Holme P, Saramaki J. Temporal networks. Springer. 2013.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
46. 46. Ghosh D, Frasca M, Rizzo A, Majhi S, Rakshit S, Alfaro-Bittner K, et al. The synchronized dynamics of time-varying networks. Phys Rep. 2022;949:1–63.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
47. 47. Guo H, Yan X, Niu Y, Zhang J. Dynamic analysis of rumor propagation model with media report and time delay on social networks. J Appl Math Comput 2023;69(3):2473–502. pmid:36846484
* View Article
* PubMed/NCBI
* Google Scholar
48. 48. Din N, Guan G, Shen S, Zhu L. Dynamical behaviors and optimal control of delayed S2IS rumor propagation model with saturated conversion function over complex networks. Commun Nonlin Sci Numer Simul. 2024;128:107603.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
49. 49. Hua S, Liu L. Coevolutionary dynamics of population and institutional rewards in public goods games. Expert systems with applications. 2024;237:121579.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
50. 50. Blaquiere A. Impulsive optimal control with finite or infinite time horizon. J Optim Theory Appl. 1985;46:431–439.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
51. 51. Chahim M, Hartl RF, Kort PM. A tutorial on the deterministic impulse control maximum principle: Necessary and sufficient optimality conditions. Eur J Oper Res. 2012;219(1):18–26.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
52. 52. Koessler F. Strategic knowledge sharing in Bayesian games. Games Econ Behav. 2004;48(2):292–320.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
53. 53. Zhang X, Chen Z, Vogel D, Yuan M, Guo C. Knowledge-sharing reward dynamics in knowledge management systems: Game theory–based empirical validation. Hum Factors Ergon Manuf Serv Ind. 2010;20(2):103–22.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
54. 54. Al-Gharaibeh RS, Ali MZ. Knowledge sharing framework: A game-theoretic approach. J Knowl Econ. 2022;13:332–66.
* View Article
* Google Scholar
Citation: Hu X, Qin Y, Yang L-X, Yang X (2025) Monetary reward mechanism for promoting online knowledge sharing: A modeling study. PLoS ONE 20(4): e0320236. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0320236
About the Authors:
Xuhui Hu
Roles: Data curation, Formal analysis, Investigation, Methodology, Software, Writing – original draft
Affiliation: School of Big Data and Software Engineering, Chongqing University, Chongqing, China
Yang Qin
Roles: Data curation, Investigation, Software, Writing – original draft
E-mail: [email protected]
Affiliation: School of Big Data and Software Engineering, Chongqing University, Chongqing, China
ORICD: https://orcid.org/0009-0006-5184-5849
Lu-Xing Yang
Roles: Conceptualization, Project administration, Resources, Writing – review & editing
Affiliation: School of Information Technology, Deakin University, Melbourne, Victoria, Australia
Xiaofan Yang
Roles: Funding acquisition, Project administration, Supervision, Validation, Writing – review & editing
Affiliation: School of Big Data and Software Engineering, Chongqing University, Chongqing, China
[/RAW_REF_TEXT]
1. Dalkir K. Knowledge management in theory and practice. Routledge; 2011.
2. Wang S, Noe RA. Knowledge sharing: A review and directions for future research. Hum Resour Manag Rev. 2010;20:115–31.
3. Aboelmaged MG. Knowledge sharing through enterprise social network (ESN) systems: Motivational drivers and their impact on employees’ productivity. J Knowl Manag. 2018;22(2):362–83.
4. Castaneda DI, Cuellar S. Knowledge sharing and innovation: A systematic review. Knowl Process Manag. 2020;27(3):159–73.
5. Deng H, Duan SX, Wibowo S. Digital technology driven knowledge sharing for job performance. J Knowl Manag. 2023;27(2).
6. Nguyen T-M, Malik A. Cognitive processes, rewards and online knowledge sharing behaviour: the moderating effect of organisational innovation. J Knowl Manag. 2020;24(6):1241–61.
7. Nwankpa J, Roumani Y, Datta P. Process innovation in the digital age of business: The role of digital business intensity and knowledge management. J Knowl Manag. 2022;26(5):1319–41.
8. Nguyen M, Malik A, Sharma P. How to motivate employees to engage in online knowledge sharing? Differences between posters and lurkers. J Knowl Manag. 2021;25(7):1811–31.
9. Nguyen M, Ngo LV, Gregory G. Motivation in organisational online knowledge sharing. J Knowl Manag. 2021;26(1):102–25.
10. Burtch G, Hong Y, Bapna R, Griskevicius V. Stimulating online reviews by combining financial incentives and social norms. Manag Sci. 2018;64(5):2065–82.
11. Wang J, Li G, Hui K-L. Monetary incentives and knowledge spillover: Evidence from a natural experiment. Manag Sci. 2021;68(5):3549–72.
12. Ozono H, Kamijo Y, Shimizu K. The role of peer reward and punishment for public goods problems in a localized society. Sci Rep 2020;10(1):8211. pmid:32427936
13. Dong Y, Sasaki T, Zhang B. The competitive advantage of institutional reward. Proc Biol Sci 2019;286(1899):20190001. pmid:30914009
14. Sun Y, Dong X, McIntyre S. Motivation of user-generated content: Social connectedness moderates the effects of monetary rewards. Market Sci. 2017;36(3):329–37.
15. Deci EL, Koestner R, Ryan RM. A meta-analytic review of experiments examining the effects of extrinsic rewards on intrinsic motivation. Psychol Bull. 1999;125(6):627–68; discussion 692–700. pmid:10589297
16. Cabrera A, Cabrera EF. Knowledge-sharing dilemmas. Org Stud. 2002;23(5):687–710.
17. Al-Alawi A, Al-Marzooqi NY, Mohammed YF. Organizational culture and knowledge sharing: Critical success factors. J Knowl Manag. 2007;11(2):22–42.
18. Halisah A, Jayasingam S, Ramayah T, Popa S. Social dilemmas in knowledge sharing: An examination of the interplay between knowledge sharing culture and performance climate. J Knowl Manag. 2021;25(7):1708–25.
19. Lai HM, Chen TT. Knowledge sharing in interest online communities: A comparison of posters and lurkers. Comput Hum Behav. 2014;35:295–306.
20. Sun N, Rau PP, Ma L. Understanding lurkers in online communities: A literature review. Comput Hum Behav. 2014;38:110–7.
21. Marett K, Joshi K. The decision to share information and rumors: Examining the role of motivation in an online discussion forum. Commun Assoc Inform Syst. 2009;24(1):47–68.
22. Nguyen M, Fry M-L, Arli D. Share or not share knowledge: Posters versus lurkers in organisational online knowledge sharing and internal marketing. Aust Market J. 2024;32(2):151–61.
23. Teo TSH, Lim VKG, Lai RYC. Intrinsic and extrinsic motivation in Internet usage. Omega. 1999;27(1):25–37.
24. Wasko MM, Faraj S. ‘It is what one does’: Why people participate and help others in electronic communities of practice. J Strat Inform Syst. 2000;9(2–3):155–73.
25. Lin H-F. Effects of extrinsic and intrinsic motivation on employee knowledge sharing intentions. J Inform Sci. 2007;33(2):135–49.
26. Nguyen T-M, Nham TP, Froese FJ, Malik A. Motivation and knowledge sharing: A meta-analysis of main and moderating effects. J Knowl Manag. 2019;23(5):998–1016.
27. Chen IYL, Chen N-S, Kinshuk . Examining the factors influencing participants’ knowledge sharing behavior in virtual learning communities. Educ Technol Soc. 2009;12(1):134–48.
28. Bock G-W, Zmud R, Kim Y-G, Lee J-N. Behavioral intention formation in knowledge sharing: Examining the roles of extrinsic motivators, social-psychological forces, and organizational climate. MIS Q. 2005;29(1):87–111.
29. Tohidinia Z, Mosakhani M. Knowledge sharing behavior and its predictors. Ind Manag Data Syst. 2010;110(4);611–631.
30. Duong MH, Han TA. Cost efficiency of institutional incentives for promoting cooperation in finite populations. Proc Math Phys Eng Sci 2021;477(2254):20210568. pmid:35153590
31. Han TA, Tran-Thanh L. Cost-effective external interference for promoting the evolution of cooperation. Sci Rep 2018;8(1):15997. pmid:30375463
32. Kirk DE. Optimal control theory: An introduction. Dover Publications. 2004.
33. Eshghi S, Khouzani MHR, Sarkar S, Venkatesh SS. Optimal patching in clustered malware epidemics. IEEE/ACM Trans Netw. 2016;24(1):283–98.
34. Huang K, Li P, Yang LX, Yang X, Tang YY. Seeking best-balanced patch-injecting strategies through optimal control approach. Secur Commun Netw. 2019;2019:2315627.
35. Huang DW, Yang LX, Li P, Yang X, Tang YY. Developing cost-effective rumor-refuting strategy through game-theoretic approach. IEEE Syst J. 2021;15(4):5034–45.
36. Huang K, Yang X, Yang LX, Zhu Y, Li G. Mitigating the impact of a false message through sequential release of clarifying messages. IEEE Trans Netw Sci Eng. 2024;11(2):1785–98.
37. Yang L, Li P, Yang X, Xiang Y, Jiang F, Zhou W. Effective quarantine and recovery scheme against advanced persistent threat. IEEE Trans Syst Man Cybern: Syst. 2021;51(10):5977–91.
38. Sun H, Yang X, Yang LX, Huang K, Li G. Impulsive artificial defense against advanced persistent threat. IEEE Trans Inform Foren Sec. 2023;18:3506–16.
39. Huang K, Yang LX, Yang X, Tang YY. Effective multiplatform advertising policy. IEEE Trans Syst Man Cybern: Syst. 2022;52(7):4483–93.
40. Danaher PJ. Optimal microtargeting of advertising. J Market Res. 2023;60(3):564–86.
41. Wang S, Liu L, Chen X. Incentive strategies for the evolution of cooperation: Analysis and optimization. Europhys Lett. 2021:136(6);68002.
42. Wang S, Chen X, Xiao Z, Szolnoki A, Vasconcelos VV. Optimization of institutional incentives for cooperation in structured populations. J R Soc Interface 2023;20(199):20220653. pmid:36722070
43. Hu J, Yang LX, Yang X, Huang K, Li G, Xiang Y. Cost-effective company response policy for product co-creation in company-sponsored online community. IEEE Trans Syst Man Cybern: Syst. 2024;54(7):4494–506.
44. McAsey M, Mou L, Han W. Convergence of the forward-backward sweep method in optimal control. Comput Optim Appl. 2012;53(1):207–26.
45. Holme P, Saramaki J. Temporal networks. Springer. 2013.
46. Ghosh D, Frasca M, Rizzo A, Majhi S, Rakshit S, Alfaro-Bittner K, et al. The synchronized dynamics of time-varying networks. Phys Rep. 2022;949:1–63.
47. Guo H, Yan X, Niu Y, Zhang J. Dynamic analysis of rumor propagation model with media report and time delay on social networks. J Appl Math Comput 2023;69(3):2473–502. pmid:36846484
48. Din N, Guan G, Shen S, Zhu L. Dynamical behaviors and optimal control of delayed S2IS rumor propagation model with saturated conversion function over complex networks. Commun Nonlin Sci Numer Simul. 2024;128:107603.
49. Hua S, Liu L. Coevolutionary dynamics of population and institutional rewards in public goods games. Expert systems with applications. 2024;237:121579.
50. Blaquiere A. Impulsive optimal control with finite or infinite time horizon. J Optim Theory Appl. 1985;46:431–439.
51. Chahim M, Hartl RF, Kort PM. A tutorial on the deterministic impulse control maximum principle: Necessary and sufficient optimality conditions. Eur J Oper Res. 2012;219(1):18–26.
52. Koessler F. Strategic knowledge sharing in Bayesian games. Games Econ Behav. 2004;48(2):292–320.
53. Zhang X, Chen Z, Vogel D, Yuan M, Guo C. Knowledge-sharing reward dynamics in knowledge management systems: Game theory–based empirical validation. Hum Factors Ergon Manuf Serv Ind. 2010;20(2):103–22.
54. Al-Gharaibeh RS, Ali MZ. Knowledge sharing framework: A game-theoretic approach. J Knowl Econ. 2022;13:332–66.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer
© 2025 Hu et al. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License: http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ (the “License”), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited. Notwithstanding the ProQuest Terms and Conditions, you may use this content in accordance with the terms of the License.
Abstract
Knowledge sharing is critical for an organization to acquire sustained competitive advantage. Bestowing monetary rewards may possibly the most direct method of stimulating online knowledge sharing. Under the monetary reward mechanism for promoting knowledge sharing, we intend to find a satisfactory knowledge-sharing promotion policy. First, based on a state evolutionary model for the knowledge-sharing community, we reduce the original problem to an optimal control model. Second, applying optimal control theory to the model, we give an algorithm for solving the model. Next, we validate the feasibility of the algorithm. Finally, we inspect the applicability of the algorithm. To our knowledge, this is the first time the optimal control modeling technique is applied to the research of knowledge sharing.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer