About the Authors:
M. Mercè Claramunt
Contributed equally to this work with: M. Mercè Claramunt, Maite Mármol
Roles Formal analysis, Investigation, Methodology, Software, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing
Affiliation: Departament de Matemàtica Econòmica, Financera i Actuarial, Universitat de Barcelona, Barcelona, Spain
Maite Mármol
Contributed equally to this work with: M. Mercè Claramunt, Maite Mármol
Roles Formal analysis, Investigation, Methodology, Software, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing
* E-mail: [email protected]
Affiliation: Departament de Matemàtica Econòmica, Financera i Actuarial, Universitat de Barcelona, Barcelona, Spain
ORCID logo https://orcid.org/0000-0002-2246-3247
Abstract
Most insurance policies include a deductible, so that a part of the claim is paid by the insured. In order to get full coverage of the claim, the insured has two options: purchase a Zero Deductible Insurance Policy or purchase an insurance policy with deductible together with Refundable Deductible Insurance. The objective of this paper is to analyze these two options and compare the premium paid by each. We define dif(P) as the difference between the premiums paid. This function depends on the parameters of the deductible applied, and we focus our attention on the sign of this difference and the calculation of the optimal deductible, that is, the values of the parameters of the deductible that allow us to obtain the greatest reduction in the premium.
Figures
Table 10
Table 11
Table 1
Fig 1
Table 2
Table 3
Table 4
Table 5
Fig 2
Fig 3
Table 6
Table 7
Fig 4
Fig 5
Fig 6
Fig 7
Fig 8
Fig 9
Table 8
Table 9
Table 10
Table 11
Table 1
Fig 1
Table 2
Citation: Claramunt MM, Mármol M (2021) Is a Refundable Deductible Insurance an advantage for the insured? a mathematical approach. PLoS ONE 16(2): e0247030. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030
Editor: Baogui Xin, Shandong University of Science and Technology, CHINA
Received: September 30, 2020; Accepted: January 29, 2021; Published: February 17, 2021
Copyright: © 2021 Claramunt, Mármol. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited.
Data Availability: All relevant data are within the manuscript. (No supporting information files)
Funding: No specific funding was received for this study.
Competing interests: The authors have declared that no competing interests exist.
1 Introduction
Currently, the car rental sector is booming and is supposed to experience an important future growth, especially in large urban centers. Specifically, the global car rental market is expected to reach a CAGR (Compound Annual Growth Rate) of 7.5 during the forecast period of 2019-2024 [1]. We could consider several reasons for this trend: a growing environmental awareness, growing traffic problems, traffic restrictions due to pollution or the explosion of car sharing.
Due to the positive evolution of this sector, companies offering insurance policies to rental companies and their customers/users have developed new strategies to complete the coverage offered and decrease the price of car hire insurance, which in some cases can represent half of the rental cost. For more information about the car rental insurance industry in Europe, see [2].
In Europe, most car rental companies offer rental insurance coverage that guarantees protection against damage, theft, and liability insurance against third parties. This is known as CDW (Collision Damage Waiver), which provides cover in the event of collision or damage, and LDW (Loss Damage Waiver), which provides cover in the event of theft or loss of use of the vehicle. These policies offer varying levels of protection against damage. In other countries, such as USA or Canada, CDW and LDW insurance must be contracted separately. Most of these insurance policies include a deductible, which in case of accident must be paid by the user to the rental company.
In order to cover the deductible, the insured has two options: He/she can purchase either an extension to a Super CDW offered by the car rental company, which is in fact a Zero Deductible Insurance, or an RDI (Refundable Deductible Insurance), which covers the cost of the deductible. In recent years, there have been online companies that, at a lower cost, cover the deductible. Then, if a claim occurs, the amount of the deductible that the car rental company has charged to the user is refunded. Thereby, if a claim occurs and the insured does not want to pay, he/she has two possibilities: purchase a Zero Deductible Insurance or a Deductible Insurance together with a Refundable Deductible Insurance.
In the actuarial literature, studies about deductibles have focused on several aspects. One of the main topics is the analysis of the problem of optimal coverage and deductible through expected utility (see [3, 4] or [5]) and stochastic dominance [6, 7]. The interaction between deductibles and bonus-malus systems and their repercussion on the efficiency of the bonus-malus system have been studied in [8–10], or [11]. Another topic is the optimal allocation of policy limits and deductibles from the viewpoint of a risk-averse policyholder [12, 13] or from the viewpoint of the insurer [14]. Although the introduction of deductibles in insurance contracts has been widely analyzed in actuarial literature, as far as we know, there are no studies concerning Refundable Deductible Insurance.
The objective of our research is to analyze the advantage the insured can have by hiring a Deductible Insurance and a Refundable Deductible Insurance, option covering the whole cost of the claim, as opposed to the alternative of directly hiring a Super CDW, that is to say a Zero Deductible Insurance policy. We measure this advantage by comparing the premium paid in these two alternatives considering different rules to share the cost of the claim between the insurer and the insured. Specifically, we worked with absolute deductible, proportional deductible, mixture of absolute deductible and proportional deductible and all-nothing deductible. For a definition of these deductibles, see [15] or [16], among others.
As a preliminary step, we will go through some concepts and facts that are useful in what follows. Notation and conventions used throughout the paper are also established. We denote by S the aggregate claim amount random variable (r.v.) of a given portfolio of policyholders over a year. Using the collective risk model S is defined as a random sum,where is a non-negative r.v. that represents the cost of the i-th claim, and N is a positive counting r.v. that represents the number of claims. re assumed to be independent and identically distributed (i.i.d.) and also independent of N (see [17] or [18]). Let be the part of the cost paid by the insured in an insurance with deductible, and , the part of the claim paid by the insurer. The r.v. is distributed as the strictly positive r.v. X, with cumulative distribution function FX(x). The survival function of X, its expected value and variance are denoted by , E(X) and V(X), respectively. From now on, for reasons of simplicity, A(X) and C(X) are denoted as A and C.
The moments of the aggregate claim amount are easily calculated from the moments of X and N. The expected value of the aggregate claim amount S is:(1)and its variance:(2)
Without deductible, the aggregate claim amount coincides with the total cost covered by the insurer. If a deductible is applied, the total cost for the insurer is calculated with the same formula than the aggregate claim amount but including only the part of each of the claims that he/she pays (C) instead of considering the whole claims (X). From now on, in order to avoid confusions, S stands for the total cost paid by the insurer.
The insurer calculates the premium considering only the part of the claim that he/she pays. If the contract includes a deductible, the moments of the total cost for the insurer are obtained from (1) and (2), substituting X by C.
Let Π be the premium paid for a Zero Deductible Insurance, ΠD the premium paid for a Deductible Insurance, and ΠR the premium paid for a Refundable Deductible Insurance, that is to say an insurance policy that covers A. To measure the effect of the two alternatives that the insured has to get full coverage, we compare Π and ΠD + ΠR. The function dif(P) measures the difference for the insured between the two options,where dif(P) is a function that depends on P, the set of parameters that defines each deductible, P = {p1, …, pj}, j ∈ N, being j the number of parameters, with . For example, for an absolute deductible (the insured pays the first a monetary units of each claim X, and the insurer pays the excess over a), j = 1 and P = {a}. Then, if Π = ΠD + ΠR, dif(P) equals to zero which implies that the two alternatives are indifferent for the insured. If Π < ΠD + ΠR, dif(P) is negative and the insured prefers to purchase just a Zero Deductible Insurance. And lastly, if Π > ΠD + ΠR, dif(P) is positive, so the insured prefers to buy a Deductible Insurance and a Refundable Deductible Insurance. This analysis depends on the type of deductible applied and the premium principle used, in other words, the mathematical method used to fix the insurance premium. In this paper, we focus our attention on two premium principles: the mean principle and the variance principle.
If we use the mean principle, the premium is calculated as the expected value of the risk plus a safety loading to this expected value,whereas if we use the variance principle, the loading is proportional to the variance,
For more information about premium principles and their properties, see [19, 20].
If the mean principle is applied, the premium of the Deductible Insurance isthe premium for the Refundable Deductible Insurance isand the premium paid for a complete insurance covering the whole claim, a Zero Deductible Insurance, is given by
Then, knowing that E(X) = E(C) + E(A), dif(P) = Π − ΠD − ΠR = 0 for any X and N and whatever deductible is used. In this case, there is no advantage from choosing one alternative or the other. Whereas, if we focus on the variance principle, it is easy to see that dif(P) is not always equal to zero, and then a deep analysis is needed in order to optimize the advantage that the insured can get.
In this framework, the paper contributes in three aspects. First we propose a theoretical framework for the market practice of hiring a Refundable Deductible Insurance policy. Second, we find a sufficient condition, fulfilled by almost all deductible types, that guarantees the advantage for the insured of the Refundable Deductible Insurance under the variance principle. And lastly, considering that the set of parameters P that defines each deductible is chosen by the insured, we present the optimal deductible parameters allowing the insured to obtain the maximum gain for different types of deductibles.
After this introduction, the paper is structured as follows. In Section 2, if the variance principle is applied, the expression of dif(P) valid for any deductible is obtained and the conditions that allow to maximize this function are presented. One of the main results obtained is that the commonotonicity of the parts of the claim covered by the insurer and the insured guarantees the advantage that the insured can obtain by hiring a Refundable Deductible Insurance policy. In Section 3, we develop the specific results for the different deductibles considered in this paper: absolute deductible, proportional deductible, mixture of absolute deductible and proportional deductible and all-nothing deductible. We show that the deductible parameters that maximize the difference obtained by the insured depend on the expected value and variance of the number of claims and the distribution of the individual claim amount. The paper ends with some conclusions.
2 Analysis and optimization of dif(P) for any deductible if the variance principle is applied
In this section the variance principle is used to calculate premiums. A general expression for dif(P) is obtained and the conditions that allow to maximize this function are presented.
Using the variance principle, the premium of the Deductible Insurance iswhereas the premium for the Refundable Deductible Insurance is given byand the premium that would be paid for a complete insurance covering all X, a Zero Deductible Insurance, is given by
The random variables A and C depend not only on X but also on the parameters of the deductible. In order to simplify the expressions, we will not make explicit these dependencies. Then, with the variance principle,(3)
Taking into account that Cov(A, C) = E(AC) − E(A)E(C) and substituting C by X − A, an alternative expression for dif(P) is obtained,(4)
We analyze this function dif(P). The first aspect is the sign of this difference. Proposition 1 establishes its positiveness under an usual condition. The second aspect studied is the calculation, if it exists, of the optimal deductible, that is, the values of the parameters of the deductible such that the insured obtains the greatest reduction in the total premium paid with the same coverage. In this section, Proposition 2, we include the first order condition for this optimization problem. Next sections are dedicated to these questions regarding the absolute deductible, the proportional deductible with maximum loss, a mixture of an absolute deductible and a proportional deductible and the all-nothing deductible.
Before Proposition 1 is presented, we introduce the definition of comonotonicity.
Definition 1. Let X and Y be two non negative r.v. that represent two different risks. They are comonotonic (see [21]) if their bivariate cumulative distribution function, FXY(x, y), satisfies FXY(x, y) = min[FX(x), FY(y)] for all x, y ≥ 0.
From an intuitive point of view, the comonotonicity of two risks means that these risks are not able to compensate each other.
Proposition 1. For a deductible such that A and C are comonotonic risks, dif(P) > 0.
Proof. If two risks are comonotonic, its covariance is positive (see [22]). Then, from (3), if A and C are comonotonic, dif(P) > 0.
Then, the comonotonicity is a sufficient condition for the positiveness of dif(P). For more information on comonotonicity, see [23–25]. The r.v.’s A and C are comonotonic in almost all deductibles, see [21]. This is the case for the absolute deductible (Section 3.1), the proportional deductible with maximum loss (Section 3.2) and a mixture of an absolute deductible and a proportional deductible (Section 3.3). In Section 3.4., we analyze a type of deductible such that A and C are not comonotonic, the all-nothing deductible.
The optimal deductible problem isw.r.t. the parameters {p1, …, pj} that define the deductible and subject to the constrains . These constrains permit obtaining the set of feasible solutions, D. In all the deductibles studied in this paper, D turns out to be an open set, and dif(P) a continuous and differentiable function in D.
Proposition 2. The values of the parameters of the deductible such that the insured obtains the greatest reduction in the global total premium paid with the same coverage fulfill, if they exist, the following system of equations (5)being . In the Poisson case, this system is reduced to
Proof. The first order condition of the optimal deductible problem isthat, taking into account the definition of dif(P) in (4), allows us to obtain (5). From (5) we see that, regarding the number of claims, only its expected value and variance affect the optimization problem and in fact, when the expected value and the variance of N are equal, the first order conditions are simplified. In the Poisson case, N ∼ Pois(λ), E(N) = V(N), so g(N) = 0, and the result presented in the proposition is obtained.
In Section 3, we apply Proposition 2 to obtain the parameters of the different deductibles that maximizes the reduction in the global total premium paid with the same coverage.
3 Analysis and optimization of dif(P): Specific results for different types of deductibles if the variance principle is applied
In this section we present the results obtained in the optimization of dif(P) for different types of deductibles under the variance principle. Specifically, we consider absolute deductible, proportional deductible, mixture of absolute deductible and proportional deductible and all-nothing deductible. In the first three types of deductibles, Proposition 1 is fulfilled, that is to say, A and C are comonotonic risks and therefore dif(P) is always positive. If the all-nothing deductible is applied, A and C are not comonotonic risks, thence dif(P) can be positive or negative, so, for the insured, the option of taking out a Deductible Insurance and a Refundable Deductible Insurance is not always better than hiring a Zero Insurance policy.
3.1 Absolute deductible
If the absolute deductible is applied, the insured pays the first a monetary units of each claim X, and the insurer pays the excess over a, X − a. Then, if an absolute deductible with parameter a ≥ 0 is applied, A and C are defined in Table 1.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Table 1. Definition of A and C if an absolute deductible with parameter a ≥ 0 is applied.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030.t001
Following [26], we define the s-th partial moment of X about the origin over (0, x0) as the partial expectation of Xs, . Hence, the expectations of A, AX and A2 are(6) (7) (8)
From (4) and using (6), (7) and (8), dif(P) is given by(9)
As dif(P) is function of only one variable, in order to find the value of a that maximizes the difference, we substitute the gradient by the derivative with respect to a. The system (5) becomes(10)
Differentiating (6), (7) and (8) with respect to a, we obtain,
Then, using these last derivatives, (10) is(11)
Proposition 3. The function dif(P) attains a global maximum on D.
Proof. The function dif(P) is a continuous and positive function in D = {a|a > 0}} and lima → ∞ dif(P) = lima → 0 dif(P)) = 0. Therefore, (11) has at least one solution and dif(P) attains a global maximum.
We consider two claim amount distributions: exponential and Pareto-Lomax.
Exponential case: If X ∼ exp(γ), γ > 0, the probability density function is given by f(x) = γe − γx, then(12) (13)
Substituting the previous expressions in (9), dif(P) is
And, substituting (12) and (13) in (11), the equation that allows to obtain the value of a that maximizes dif(P) is
The value of a that fulfills the previous expression, a*, depends on the relationship between E(N) and V(N). So, if E(N) > V(N), a* ; if E(N) < V[N], , and lastly, when E(N) = V(N), . If N is Poisson distributed with parameter λ, the optimal value for a coincides with the mean claim amount, the maximum difference is and hence, for the insured, the best option is to purchase a deductible insurance with a = E(X) and a refundable insurance that covers a.
In Fig 1, we plot dif(P), in the Poisson-exponential case, as a function of a for different values of .
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Fig 1. dif(F) as a function of a in the Poisson-exponential case for δ = 0.03 and λ = 1 for E(X) = 2, 5, 10, 15.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030.g001
Pareto-Lomax case: If X ∼ Pareto(θ, ν), the probability density function is given by f(x) = θνθ(ν + x) − θ−1 and the mean is , ν > 0, θ > 2 (so that the variance is finite). Then,
Substituting the previous expressions in (11)
If E(N) > V(N), , if E(N) = V(N) (Poisson case) , and if E(N) < V(N), .
Summarizing the results for the exponential and the Pareto-Lomax cases, in Table 2, the optimal values of a that maximizes dif(P) are included.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Table 2. Optimal a in absolute deductible in the Poisson-exponential and Poisson-Pareto-Lomax cases.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030.t002
We now consider that N is Poisson distributed with parameter λ, and we do not specify the distribution of X. Now, dif(P) is linear on δ and depends on a, the only parameter of the deductible,
The value of a that maximizes dif(P) is the solution towhich can be rewritten as(14)
The solution to (14) depends only on the distribution of X. Explicit expressions have been obtained in the previous two subsections for the exponential and the Pareto-Lomax distributions. For other claim amount distributions, only numerical solutions can be found. We calculate the optimal value of a and the maximum difference reached for several distributions of the claim amount. The parameters of the distributions are such that the expected value and the variance of the claim amount is the same, so the premium with a zero deductible insurance Π would be the same. The Pareto-Lomax distribution is not included in the comparison because there is no combination of θ and ν that fulfills E(X)2 = V(X), as in the exponential case. For the lognormal distribution, with parameters μ and σ, (14) is(15)that, for the specific choice of parameters that fulfills E(X)2 = V(X), in order to compare with the exponential distribution, we obtain
If the individual claim amount follows an Inverse-Gaussian distribution, X ∼ IG(μ, λ), μ > 0, λ > 0, the probability distribution function is given by , the expected value is E(X) = μ and its variance . The combination of μ and λ that fulfills E(X)2 = V(X) is μ = λ. Then, the optimal value of a is obtained fromequation that can be solved numerically.
In Table 3, the results of the optimal value a* and the maximum value of dif(P) depending on E(N) and δ are presented for an Exponential, a Lognormal and an Inverse-Gaussian distribution.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Table 3. Optimal value of a and difference (a*, dif(a*)) for Exp(γ), Log(μ, σ) and IG(μ, λ) claim amount distributions.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030.t003
Table 3 shows that the maximum difference is proportional to the expected value of N and to the safety loading, which is the highest in the exponential case and the lowest in the Lognormal case. For each value of E(X), the optimal value of a, a*, is the lowest in the Lognormal case and the highest in the Inverse-Gaussian case.
3.2Proportional deductible
In this section, we focus our attention on the proportional deductible. We work with two types of proportional deductible: a first type in which the insured pays a percentage α of each claim, and, a second type in which we include a maximum loss for the insured, B. In a deductible with participation α ∈ (0, 1), A and C are defined in Table 4.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Table 4. Definition of A and C if a deductible with participation α ∈ (0, 1) is applied.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030.t004
In this case, E(AX) = αE(X2), E(A2) = α2 E(X2) and E(A) = αE(X), then
Using (5), the value α that maximizes the difference has to fulfill(16)
Proposition 4. The function dif(P) attains a global maximum in .
Proof. The function dif(P) is a continuous and positive function in D = {α|α ∈ (0, 1)} and limα → 1 dif(P) = limα → 0 dif(P)) = 0. As the second factor in (16) is always different from 0, the critical point, , is a global maximum of dif(P).
Independently of the distribution of N and X, is the value that maximizes the difference. Then, the maximum value of the difference is . If N ∼ Pois(λ), the maximum difference is .
Now, we generalize the proportional deductible including a maximum loss for the insured. In Table 5, a deductible with participation α ∈ (0, 1) and a maximum loss B > 0 is defined.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Table 5. Definition of A and C if a deductible with participation α ∈ (0, 1) with limit B > 0 is applied.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030.t005
If B tends to infinity, the first type of proportional deductible is obtained as a particular case.
If the deductible with participation α ∈ (0, 1) with limit B > 0 is applied,(17) (18) (19)
From (4), dif(P) can be rewritten as
The deductible depends on two parameters, α and B. The partial derivatives with respect to α and B, from (17), (18) and (19), are
Then, (5) is(20)
The function dif(P) is a continuous and positive function in D = {(α, B)|α ∈ (0, 1), B > 0}. The critical points of the maximization problem are the solutions of the system of Eq (20). If we evaluate the function at the boundaries of D, it is easy to see that limα → 0 dif(P) = limB → 0 dif(P) = 0, limα → 1 dif(P) equals to dif(P) in the absolute deductible case with parameter a = B, and limB → ∞ dif(P) equals to dif(P) in the proportional deductible case. Therefore, we are not able to guarantee the existence of a global maximum for any N and X. Nevertheless, if N is Poisson distributed, we proof (see Proposition 5) that a global maximum does not exist. In this proposition, considering that the insured can choose only one of the parameters that define the deductible while the other is fixed by the insurer, we also obtain marginal maximums.
Proposition 5. If N ∼ Pois(λ), there is no value of (B, α) that maximizes (22), but marginal optimums exist. For a fixed B, maximizes the difference. For a fixed the maximum does not exist, and if the maximum point, if it exists, fulfills .
Proof. If N ∼ Pois(λ), dif(P) is(21)and (20) is(22)
From the second equation in (22), knowing that , we obtain . Substituting this value in the first equation, it is reduced to , which is impossible because the integral is always different from 0. Then, there is no value of (B, α) that maximizes (22).
From (the second equation of (22)), is the critical point. As the sign of at is negative, the critical point is a maximum.
From (the first equation of (22)), the value of B that maximizes does not exist because is always different from 0 as , and if the value of B that maximizes has to fulfill .
Poisson-Exponential case: If N ∼ Pois(λ) and X ∼ exp(γ), following Proposition 5, we know that there is no value of (α, B) that maximizes (21), but marginal optimums exist. For a fixed B, maximizes the difference and for a fixed α > 0.5, the value maximizes dif(P). For example, assuming γ = 0.6, δ = 0.03 and λ = 1, dif(P) as a function of α and B is plotted in Fig 2.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Fig 2. dif(F) in the Poisson-exponential case with δ = 0.03, λ = 1, γ = 0.6.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030.g002
Poisson-Pareto case: If N ∼ Pois(λ) and c for a fixed B, maximizes dif(P) and for a fixed , also maximizes the difference. For example, if θ = 3, δ = 0.03 and λ = 1, dif(P) is plotted in Fig 3.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Fig 3. dif(F) in the Poisson-Pareto case with δ = 0.03, λ = 1, θ = 3.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030.g003
Poisson-Lognormal case: If X ∼ LN(μ, σ), for a fixed , the optimal value of B is the one that fulfils , which can be written as,(23)
In this case, it is not possible to obtain analytical results of the value B that optimizes the difference. Some numerical results are presented in Table 6 for different values of .
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Table 6. Optimal B if the proportional deductible with limit is applied in the Poisson-Lognormal case for .
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030.t006
From Table 6, we see that B* decreases with α and if α = 1, we have in fact an absolute deductible and thus (23) is reduced to (15).
3.3 Mixture of absolute deductible and proportional deductible
In a mixture of absolute deductible with a > 0 and proportional deductible with α ∈ (0, 1), the insured pays the first a monetary units of each claim X, pays a if the claim amount is greater than a and less than , and if the claim amount is greater than the proportional deductible is applied and the insured pays a percentage α of the claim amount. A and C are defined in Table 7.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Table 7. Definition of A and C if a mixture of absolute deductible a > 0 and proportional deductible α ∈ (0, 1) is applied.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030.t007
We define the different elements needed in the optimization of dif(P):
This deductible depends on two parameters. We calculate the partial derivatives with respect to α and a,
And the system of equations that allows us to obtain the critical points is,(24)
The function dif(P) is a continuous and positive function in D = {(α, a)|α ∈ (0, 1), a > 0}. We evaluate dif(P) at the boundaries of D: limα → 1 dif(P) = lima → ∞ dif(P) = 0, limα → 0 dif(P) equals to dif(P) in the absolute deductible case and lima → 0 dif(P) equals to dif(P) in the proportional deductible case. As in the proportional deductible with limit B, this analysis does not allow us to assure the existence of a global maximum for any N and X. However, if N is Poisson distributed, we proof (see Proposition 5) that a global maximum does not exist and, additionally, we obtain marginal maximums.
Proposition 6. If N ∼ Pois(λ), there is no value of (a, α) that maximizes (25), but marginal optimums exist. For a fixed a, maximizes the difference. For a fixed , the maximum does not exist, and if the maximum point, if it exists, fulfills .
Proof. If N ∼ Pois(λ),and the system of Eq (24) isor alternatively(25)
From the second equation of (25), knowing that , we obtain . Substituting this value in the first equation, we obtain , which is impossible because the integral is always different from 0. Then, there is no value of (a, α) that maximizes (25).
From , is the critical point. As the sign of at is negative, the critical point is a maximum.
From , the first equation of (25), if , the value of a that maximizes does not exist because is always different from 0. If the value of a that maximizes has to fulfill .
Poisson-Exponential case: For X ∼ exp(γ), if , the value of a that optimizes the difference is obtained from the equation that has no explicit solution.
We can visualize graphically the behavior of dif(P) and its optimal values. For example, if γ = 0.6, δ = 0.03 and λ = 1, dif(P) is plotted in Fig 4.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Fig 4. dif(P) in the Poisson-exponential case with δ = 0.03, λ = 1, γ = 0.6.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030.g004
The function dif(P) is plotted for different values of α, with δ = 0.03, λ = 1 and γ = 0.6 (Fig 5) and for different values of a with δ = 0.03, λ = 1 and γ = 0.6 (Fig 6).
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Fig 5. dif(P) for α = 0.1, 0.2, 0.3, 0.4, 0.5 in the Poisson-exponential case with δ = 0.03, λ = 1, γ = 0.6.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030.g005
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Fig 6. dif(P) for a = 1, 1.2, 1.4, 1.6, 1.8 in the Poisson-exponential case with δ = 0.03, λ = 1, γ = 0.6.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030.g006
Poisson-Pareto case: If X ∼ Pareto(θ, 1), θ > 2, the value of a that optimizes the difference is obtained from the equation .
In Fig 7, a graphical illustration of dif(P) is included for θ = 3, δ = 0.03 and λ = 1.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Fig 7. dif(P) in the Poisson-Pareto case with δ = 0.03, λ = 1, θ = 0.6.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030.g007
Partial analysis of dif(P) with respect to a and α are plotted in Fig 8 and in Fig 9, respectively.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Fig 8. dif(P) for α = 0.1, 0.2, 0.3, 0.4 in the Poisson-Pareto case with δ = 0.03, λ = 1, θ = 3.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030.g008
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Fig 9. dif(P) for a = 1, 1.2, 1.4, 1.6, 1.8 in the Poisson-Pareto case with δ = 0.03, λ = 1, θ = 3.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030.g009
In the figures obtained for the exponential case (Figs 5 and 6) and for the Pareto case (Figs 8 and 9), we can observe a similar behavior in the optimization problem with respect to a and α.
Poisson-Lognormal case: If X ∼ LN(μ, σ), in order to obtain the optimal value of a that maximizes dif(P) for values of , the integral can be written as,
Due to the impossibility of analytically solving the previous equation, Table 8 shows some numerical results from which we see that a* decreases with α.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Table 8. Optimal value of a in the Poisson-Lognormal case for .
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030.t008
3.4 All-nothing deductible
In this section, we analyze the all-nothing deductible with participation M > 0. The idea is that if the individual claim amount, X, is less than M, the insurer pays the whole claim, but if X is greater than M, the insurer does not pay anything (see [15]).
In Table 9, A and C are defined.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Table 9. All-nothing deductible with participation M.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030.t009
This deductible does not fulfill Proposition 1 because A and C are not commonotic risks. Then, the following results are not focused on obtaining the optimal deductible for the insured because it is not possible to maintain that the function dif(P) is always positive.
If the all-nothing deductible is applied, E(AX) = E(A2) = E(X2) − HX2(M), and E(A) = E(X) − HX(M). Hence, the expression for dif(P) is(26)
If N ∼ Pois(λ), then dif(P) = 0 regardless of the claim amount distribution. Then, in the Poisson case, for the insured it is the same to purchase a Zero Deductible Insurance policy or a Deductible Insurance policy together with a Refundable Deductible Insurance policy.
Knowing that E(X) − HX(M)>0, we can observe in (26) that the sign of dif(P) depends on the sign of V(N) − E(N). Then, dif(P) can be positive or negative. The explanation is that, in this deductible, A and C are not commonotic risks (see [21]), and therefore the initial hypothesis of this paper is not fulfilled. That is to say, in this deductible, Cov(A, C) is not a positive value. In fact, knowing that E(AC) = E(AX) − E(A2) = 0, Cov(A, C) = −E(A)E(C)<0. From (3), the positiveness of Cov(A, C) is a sufficient, but not necessary, condition for the positiveness of dif(P). We are only interested in the situations in which dif(F) is positive, therefore we impose that V(N)>E(N).
In order to obtain the value that maximizes dif(P), we need the following two previous derivatives,and from (5), the first order condition is,(27)
Considering that HX(M) is a continuous and increasing function in D = {M|M > 0}, with HX(0) = 0 and limM → ∞ HX = E(X), we can assure the existence of a critical point. It is easy to see that dif′′(P) is always negative, then the critical point is a maximum.
In the exponential case, (27) is (2γM + 2)e − Mγ = 1 and for the Pareto(θ, ν), it is(28)
In Table 10, some numerical results for the exponential distribution are obtained.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Table 10. Optimal value of M in the exponential case.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030.t010
If X follows a Pareto(θ, ν) distribution, the optimal values of M are obtained solving numerically (28). The results are shown in Table 11.
[Figure omitted. See PDF.]
Table 11. Optimal value of M in the Pareto case.
https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030.t011
If X ∼ LN(μ, σ), then (27) is,that implies ln M = (μ + σ2), hence the value of M that maximizes dif(P) is M = e(μ + σ2).
4 Conclusions
In this paper, we present a theoretical framework to analyze the advantage that the insured can obtain by purchasing a Refundable Deductible Insurance policy. Several principles can be applied by the insurer to calculate premiums: if the mean principle is applied, this advantage is null, whereas with the variance principle, the commonotonicity of the parts of the claim covered by the insurer and the insured guarantees the advantage.
The deductible parameters that maximize the advantage obtained by the insured depend on the expected value and variance of the number of claims and the distribution of the individual claim amount. We conclude that the existence and the value of the maximums depend on the type of deductible applied. We proof the existence of a global maximum if an absolute deductible or a proportional deductible are applied. In the proportional deductible case, we find that if the insured chooses to pay the fifty per cent of each claim, the advantage obtained by purchasing a Refundable Deductible Insurance policy is the maximum one. In the absolute deductible case, explicit expressions of the part of the claim paid by the insured that maximizes the advantage are obtained for several distributions of the claim amount and the number of claims. In the other cases (proportional deductible with limit and mixture of absolute and proportional deductible), if the number of claims is Poisson distributed, we proof that the global maximum does not exist.
The results of the paper can help the insured in his/her decision-making process regarding risk coverage.
Citation: Claramunt MM, Mármol M (2021) Is a Refundable Deductible Insurance an advantage for the insured? a mathematical approach. PLoS ONE 16(2): e0247030. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0247030
1. Car Rental Market—Growth, Trends, and Forecast 2019-2024. Report by researchandmarkets.com; 2019.
2. European Comission. Study on consumers’ decision making in insurance services: a behavioural economics perspective. Final Report. Directorate-General for Justice and Consumers. https://ec.europa.eu/info/sites/info/files/countryfichesen.pdf; 2017.
3. Arrow K. Optimal insurance and generalized deductibles. Scandinavian Actuarial Journal. 1974;1:1–42.
4. Machina MJ. Non-expected utility and the robustness of the classical insurance paradigm. The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance Theory, 1995;20:9–50.
5. Schlesinger H. The optimal level of deductibility in insurance contracts. The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 1981;48(3):465–481.
6. Gollier C and Schlesinger H. Arrow’s theorem on the optimality of deductibles: A stochastic dominance approach. Economic Theory, 1996;7:359–363.
7. Schlesinger H. Insurance demand without the expected–utility paradigm. The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 1997;64(1):19–39.
8. Pitrebois S, Walhin JF and Denuit M. Bonus–malus systems with varying deductibles. ASTIN Bulletin, 2005;35(1):261–274.
9. Lemaire J, Zi H. High deductibles instead of bonus–malus. Can it work?. ASTIN Bulletin, 1994;24(1):75–86.
10. Ragulina O. Bonus–malus systems with different claim types and varying deductibles. Modern Stochastics: Theory and Applications, 2017;4(2):141–159.
11. Denuit M, Marechal X, Pitrebois S and Walhin JF. Actuarial Modelling of Claim Counts: Risk Classification, Credibility and Bonus-Malus Systems. John Wiley and Sons; 2007.
12. Cheung KC. Optimal allocation of policy limits and deductibles. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 2007;41(3):382–391.
13. Hua L and Cheung KC. Stochastic orders of scalar products with applications. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 2008;42(3):865–872.
14. Hua L and Cheung KC. Worst allocations of policy limits and deductibles. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 2008,43(1):93–98.
15. Denuit M and Charpentier A. Mathématiques de l’assurance non-vie. Economica; 2004.
16. Cizek P, Härdle WK and Weron R. Statistical Tools for Finance and Insurance. Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg; 2005.
17. Dickson D. Insurance Risk and Ruin. Cambridge University Press; 2016.
18. Panjer H and Willmot GE. Insurance Risk Models. Society of Actuaries; 1992.
19. Goovaerts MJ, De Vylder F and Haezendonck J. Insurance Premiums: theory and applications. ASTIN Bulletin, 1984:15(1):70–72.
20. Kass R, Goovaerts M, Dhaene J and Denuit M. Modern Actuarial Risk Theory. New York. Kluwer Academic Publishers; 2002.
21. Wang S and Dhaene J. Comonotonicity, correlation order and premium principles. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 1998;22(3):235–242.
22. Egozcue M, Fuentes Garcia L, Wong WK and Zitikis R. The covariance sign of transformed random variables with applications to economics and finance. IMA Journal of Management Mathematics, 2011;22(3):291–300.
23. Dhaene J and Goovaerts MJ. Dependency of risks and stop-loss order. Astin Bulletin, 1996;26:201–212.
24. Dhaene J, Wang S, Young VR and Goovaerts M. Comonotonicity and maximal stop-loss preiums. Bulletin of the Swiss Association of Actuaries, 2000; 2:99–113.
25. Dhaene J, Denuit M, Goovaerts MJ, Kaas R and Vyncke D. The concept of comonotonicity in actuarial science and finance: theory. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 2002;31(1):3–33.
26. Winkler R, Roodman GM and Britney RR. The Determination of Partial Moments. Management Science, 1972;19(3):290–296.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer
© 2021 Claramunt, Mármol. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License: http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ (the “License”), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited. Notwithstanding the ProQuest Terms and Conditions, you may use this content in accordance with the terms of the License.
Abstract
Specifically, the global car rental market is expected to reach a CAGR (Compound Annual Growth Rate) of 7.5 during the forecast period of 2019-2024 [1]. Due to the positive evolution of this sector, companies offering insurance policies to rental companies and their customers/users have developed new strategies to complete the coverage offered and decrease the price of car hire insurance, which in some cases can represent half of the rental cost. In Europe, most car rental companies offer rental insurance coverage that guarantees protection against damage, theft, and liability insurance against third parties. If the contract includes a deductible, the moments of the total cost for the insurer are obtained from (1) and (2), substituting X by C. Let Π be the premium paid for a Zero Deductible Insurance, ΠD the premium paid for a Deductible Insurance, and ΠR the premium paid for a Refundable Deductible Insurance, that is to say an insurance policy that covers A. To measure the effect of the two alternatives that the insured has to get full coverage, we compare Π and ΠD + ΠR. The function dif(P) measures the difference for the insured between the two options,where dif(P) is a function that depends on P, the set of parameters that defines each deductible, P = {p1, …, pj}, j ∈ N, being j the number of parameters, with .
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer