1. Introduction
Recently, online car-hailing services such as Uber and Didi Chuxing have been on the rise, with their low-price, high-quality model, convenience, and other advantages impacting the traditional taxi market. This has underlined the poor service and refusal to take passengers among some taxi drivers; however, taxi drivers have maintained pressure against local governments by interest struggle [1]. In addition, the rapid development of online car-hailing services has caused a number of problems related to a lack of supervision, hidden crime, disturbance to the taxi market, and allowing taxis to operate unlicensed, which has triggered in the public transport industry a new round of competition and game [2]. On July 28, 2016, the Ministry of Transport and six other ministries issued the “Guidance on Deepening Reform to Advance the Healthy Development of the Taxi Industry” and “Interim Measures for Online Car-Hailing Business Service Management” (hereafter referred to collectively as the “New Deal”). For the first time, the Interim Measures made the legal status of online car-hailing services clear at national level, defining them as taxi companies and referring to both traditional taxis and online car-hailing services collectively as taxis. By January 2, 2018, the consultation opinions for local taxi regulations had been introduced in Beijing, Tianjin, Shanghai, Shenzhen, etc. with more than 100 cities around the whole nation, which aims at supervising the online car-hailing service companies and making them take social responsibility by traditional methods, in order to obtain balance of the two market subjects’ interests for taxi enterprises and online car-hailing service companies. While traditional methods of supervision only disturb the market, the online car-hailing service market has gradually formed strategies by which to cope with these supervision methods and has incorporated them into its market operating costs [3]; however, this has exacerbated certain social problems. At the second collective learning meeting of the Political Bureau of the CPC (the Communist Party of China) Central Committee, General Secretary Xi Jin-ping emphasized that we should have a deep understanding of the current situation and big data trends, along with their impact on economic and social development, in order to make the community of shared future in cyberspace better serve China’s economic and social development and improve people’s lives. Therefore, questions of how to make the government provide differentiated traffic governance policies to balance the two market subjects’ (online car-hailing service companies and taxi companies) interests and ensure fair competition, and ensure they are fulfilling their social responsibility, have become urgent problems to be solved.
2. Literature Review
Without social responsibility, enterprises and the local government supervision departments both probably take a profiteering attitude, which leads to the illegal operation of enterprises, etc. to a certain degree [4, 5]. As the local government has inherent advantages in the external institutional mechanism and can institute policies regarding enterprises’ social responsibility, it has played a positive role in promoting the social responsibility of enterprises [6–8]. Over the past two years, new policies in each city have lacked a common basis for laws and specific measures, and the effects of these policies are not yet clear, which makes governance and law enforcement difficult. Online car-hailing service companies have not yet established a sound management system, safety management system, passenger complaint mechanism, or service quality assurance system [9]. For example, drivers are not specially trained or certified; many foreign vehicles have begun to operate in the market; the platforms do not track the vehicle’s status following registration; and the platforms can temporarily increase prices at random. In addition, the no-governance of taxis and related services have caused driver to arbitrarily choose the order on the platform and decreased overall turnover, leading to a lack of passenger safety, high travel costs, difficulties with car-hailing, and other issues [10, 11]. The irresponsible behaviors of taxi and online car-hailing service companies face positively impact network externalities and negatively externality of traffic safety and public trust, making the design of governance policies particularly complicated. Irresponsible behaviors of taxi and online car-hailing service companies are restricted by local government control and market competition simultaneously [12]. The local government can reduce the negative externality of taxi and online car-hailing service companies and the irresponsible behaviors of enterprises by improving governance policies so as to establish a regulatory model that balances tradition with modernity [13].
Many domestic and foreign scholars have discussed the influence of government governance on the social responsibility of taxi enterprises from different angles and in different fields. Calo and Rosenblat [14] built an end-to-end framework called deep supply-demand (SD) to study how sharing-economy firms such as Uber and Airbnb facilitate trusted transactions between strangers on digital platforms. Hall and Krueger provided [15] the first comprehensive analysis of the labor market for Uber’s driver-partners according to both survey and administrative data. Kim, Kibum, and others [16] built a time-series regression model, controlling for various factors that may affect taxi trips, and found that taxi drivers have been forced to change their means of conducting business in order to retain their market position, such that the sharing economy has transformed the existing market in a positive and welfare-enhancing way. Fan Lizeng and KoIllSang [17] employed a conceptual framework on the determinants of adopting car sharing services based on information processing and literature on collaborative consumption and found, after studying the responses from 599 Chinese Didi mobile application users, several factors that have a positive influence on user adoption of car sharing services. Wang and Zhao [18] analyzed the competitive strategies of Didi and the challenges brought by regulation and provided several suggestions for Didi, such as improving the interface design of the platform and the order allocation process, so as to increase user engagement and loyalty. Posen [19] studied regulation trends in the taxi industry and the growing challenges faced by Uber and suggested that Uber should not be forced to comply with outdated regulations but rather that experimental governances could allow consumers to make the consumer’ choice. Regarding “Internet accelerated speed,” Zhang and Zhang [20] highlighted the relatively high safety risk for passenger transportation regarding online car-hailing services in China based on government regulations for such services, stating that the government should improve and complete the related supervision legislation and pattern, management approach. Zhang Ruixue [21] discussed, using a multiple-streams framework that included a problem stream, policy stream, and political stream, how the “New Deal” entered decision-makers’ awareness and was promoted to the policy agenda. Sal-man and Cruz [22] studied the influence of the government’s strategy of guiding the duopoly market on consumer welfare by constructing the duopoly Stackelberg game model. Yu and Yu [23] applied complex oligopoly dynamics theory in games of incomplete information, analyzed dynamic behaviors of Bayesian games, and proposed a dynamic Cournot model with asymmetric information. Zheng and Zhang [24] studied duopoly manufacturers’ decision-making considering green technology investment and under a cap-and-trade system, finding a relationship between the carbon emission of unit products and the market share of an enterprise. Zhang and Wang [25] analyzed how the introduction of rail transport services affects port competition, building a two-stage game model based on the Hotelling Model, which consists of two ports and one rail operator, thus offering support for decision-making towards comprehensive transportation management in coastal zones. Ning [26] suggested that the paradox of government preference results from the duality of irresponsible corporate behaviors. But they did not apply the Cournot duopoly theory model to the actual problem. Chen Yifeng [27] studied the group buying pricing strategy for duopoly merchants based on the Bertrand model with a static pricing mechanism and used an example to analyze the sensitivities of main factors on the key parameters.
These studies have pointed out that local governments could reduce transaction costs of companies by reducing the initial emission rights of monopolies and increasing the verification probability or introduce an emission auction mechanism or similar thing to promote social welfare. Some of the above studies focused on local government-specific issues that affect corporate responsibility for consumers, employees, and the environment, and qualitative analysis is more; on the lack of local government participation in decision-making regarding online car-hailing services; on local government participation therein, but without considering tracking and cooperation mechanisms; and on the game model used in the duopoly market (while the Cournot model has rarely been used); and some studies without game analysis focused on the price between the online car-hailing service companies and the local government [7, 28]. In addition, prior studies have not taken into account the impact of local government preferences and local government enforcement on regulatory policies. In reality, the purpose of government governance is to restrict the irresponsible behaviors of enterprises through governance measures. When faced with the governance measures of local governments, these two enterprises will be resistant to local government governance driven by the goal of maximizing profits; and the number of oligopolies is an important factor influencing the competition strategy of the oligopolistic market. The local government has to reconcile differences in terms of not only social and corporate interests but also implementation. Because of the inadequacy of the existing literature and the number of oligopolies is less, in this paper, on the basis of summarizing the achievements of the predecessors, the Cournot duopoly game model is extended and applied to the practice of such a situation, combines local government governance and service product competition, and introduces local government preferences and local government execution factors [26]. Through the construction of a mixed Cournot duopoly game model of the local government and enterprise, the relationships among local government preferences, local government executive ability, and local government governance of enterprises’ irresponsible behavior are considered. Accordingly, a governance program is proposed to balance companies’ interests while ensuring they fulfill their social responsibility.
3. Model Building
3.1. Problem Description
To manage the irresponsible behavior of online car-hailing service and taxi companies, the local government has promulgated certain policies (e.g., the “New Policy”) [29]. However, online car-hailing service and taxi companies together constitute an oligopoly under such policies. Taxi companies are more responsible, and they manage and serve in accordance with social expectations, while online car-hailing service companies act irresponsibly as they take to production that is lower than the social expectations [30, 31]. In the tripartite interaction between local government, taxi companies, and irresponsible online car-hailing service companies are subject to two direct constraints: one is the market pressure from taxi companies’ competition; the other is the mandatory pressure from local government. The local government impacts the network of car companies indirectly through the transmission of the product service market (as illustrated in Figure 1). Irresponsible behaviors of the local government-controlled enterprises can be divided into three stages: (1) local government promulgates the management policy of irresponsible enterprises—that is, compensates the victim (stakeholders)
3.2. Model Construction
Definition 1.
The taxi companies and online car-hailing service companies provide travel services of equal quality—i.e., the two modes consume the same expenses for the same traveled distance—thus, the price competition of the two enterprises depends mainly on passenger traffic. Set passenger traffic as
Assumption 2.
The taxi companies and online car-hailing service companies have no fixed payment cost, while all expenses paid to stakeholders change with changes in passenger traffic. Taxi companies run completely responsibly, so their short-term cost function Fc(q1) can be expressed as
According to the above assumptions, the benefit functions for taxi and online car-hailing service companies can be derived, respectively, as follows:
Assumption 3.
The local government is rational and only focuses on the short-term effect of enterprises’ behaviors, while the local government utility function is not only influenced by consumers’ surplus and all payment by the enterprises to other stakeholders, but also by the benefit objective of enterprises [32]. The local government shows different preferences for social benefit objectives composed of consumers’ surplus and payment by enterprises to stakeholders and the enterprises’ benefit objectives composed of the enterprises’ benefit. The local government’s preference for the above objectives is represented by weight,
4. Equilibrium Analysis
According to the above analysis and assuming the model established is a mixed Cournot duopoly dynamic game model under perfect information [33], as
4.1. Benefit Decision in Duopolistic Market
Premised on the predicted punishment cost in the third stage of
Equations (4) and (5) show that the benefit functions of taxi and online car-hailing service companies are strict convex functions, thus solving
Adding (8) and (9) can derive the gross equilibrium passenger traffic
If the two enterprises are all responsible, the social benefits are the largest, which implies
It is clear that the following relation exists when the car-hailing enterprise is irresponsible (
It can be concluded from the above relation that the enterprise benefits and social benefits are both contrary and unified. When the irresponsible behaviors of online car-hailing service companies are not regulated, the social benefits will be significantly harmed; however, the irresponsible behaviors of online car-hailing service companies stimulate an increase in total social passenger traffic, which can, in turn, promote an increase in social benefits to a certain degree. In practice, the above conclusion can explain the contradiction when local governments regulate the irresponsible behaviors of enterprises.
With other conditions being fixed, the enterprises’ competitive edge can be measured by their benefits. If we subtract (4) from (5) to obtain the benefit difference between taxi companies and online car-hailing service companies and substitute (8) and (9), we obtain
According to
It can be concluded from the above relation that, with other conditions being fixed, when
When
As the Nash equilibrium solution for the two enterprises represents actual passenger traffic,
Considering the relation in (16), it can be derived that when
In sum, the key to reining in the irresponsible behaviors of online car-hailing service companies lies in suppressing the economic motivation for those behaviors. When the irresponsible behaviors are not worthwhile, pressure from market competition will compel them to return to normal practice or weed it out. Thus, increased punishment from local government imposed on online car-hailing service companies to make their irresponsible behaviors submarginal is a powerful measure to propel those enterprises to assume their own social responsibilities.
4.2. Local Government’s Regulatory Policies
In the first stage, the local government will select the regulatory policy
Firstly, it is needed to define value range of
Meanwhile,
As
The value range in (19) shows that the upper limit value of governmental regulatory policy is
Equation (19) also shows that when
Solve the maximum value point of
Solve first derivative of
Let
Solve second derivative of
As
According to the above relation, the maximum value point of
(1) When
Thus it is concluded that when
(2) When
As a result of
Thus the following conclusion can be drawn—i.e., when
(3) When
Combining the above relations, it is known that k* is maximum value point of
As
① When
② When
And, according to (21), when
Thus it is concluded that when
Discussion and analysis by synthesizing the above three cases can well explain the swinging of local government between enhanced governance and no-governance in reality. In addition, the above analysis also shows that no matter what value the local governmental preference
Analysis of the above three cases also reveals that no matter how much the local government values social benefits, it may still deregulate the industry in certain contexts, thereby leading to a rise in irresponsible behaviors of online car-hailing service companies. The key to understanding these illogical behaviors of local government lies in understanding the complex internal relationship between enterprises’ benefits and social benefits, as mentioned above [34]. This indicates that if the local government only focuses on current social benefits and ignores long-term social benefits, such as the sustainable development of society, it will fail to effectively suppress enterprises' irresponsible behaviors.
5. Numerical Analysis
To verify the above conclusions, the parameter value of
(1) Assuming the travel service industry has a narrow margin, set
[figures omitted; refer to PDF]
Figure 2 shows that governmental preference
① Figure 2(a) shows that sometimes the strength
② Figure 2(a) shows that when
This phenomenon reveals that, under certain conditions, the monopolistic profit is greater than the duopolistic gross profit. Now, the real motive of the local government is not to protect the benefits of stakeholders, but to eliminate competition via legal paths to obtain monopolistic profit. A similar phenomenon exists objectively in the real world. Some local governments use legal means to expel foreign products for the purpose of protecting local financial revenue, thereby forming local protectionism.
③ Figure 2(a) shows that when
④ Figure 2(b) shows that the strength of governance policies of a local government with low executive ability
(2) Assuming that the travel service industry has narrow margin, set
[figures omitted; refer to PDF]
The following conclusions can be drawn from the results:
① Figure 3(a) shows that the benefit function
② Figure 3(b) shows that, under different governmental executive abilities
(3) Assuming that the travel service industry has a narrow margin, set
[figures omitted; refer to PDF]
The following conclusions can be drawn from the results:
① Figure 4(a) shows that the equilibrium passenger traffic
② Figure 4(b) shows that the gross equilibrium output
If this model is applied to the actual decision-making of local governments, the policy-makers may conduct numerical research and analysis before issuing regulatory policies; that is, based on different levels of governmental preference
① Considering different actual conditions, determine the reasonable value range and change the step size of governmental preference
② According to all of the above-mentioned actual situations, all actual situations and their corresponding decision-making suggestions should be summarized after carrying out corresponding numerical analyses and the optimal decision-making approach selected based on current market conditions. A relatively fair and equitable suggested conclusion can then be put forward [36]. The local government’s disposal scheme can be formulated under different
③ The mixed Cournot game entails not only confrontation and conflict. Under a clear market mechanism and local government management, it also includes cooperation elements and conflict and cooperation may overlap and coexist [37]. In reality, taxi companies and car-hailing service companies are both bounded rationality, but the two companies can make themselves completely rational by paying certain information costs [38]. Under a situation of mixed rational behavior, the two parties in the Cournot game model usually need to make strategic choices in two areas: rational behavioral decision-making and output decision-making [39]. It is worth mentioning that a series of studies conducted based on the mixed dynamic game model established in this paper. It is found that through solving equilibrium solution and analyzing the stability of the equilibrium solution, under the mixed rational behavior, the two sides of the game will obtain the stable solution consistent with the static Cournot model under completely rational behavior by the dynamic adjustment strategy, which shows that the game mechanism designed in this paper is effective [40]. When the socioeconomic environment and decision-making issues are more complicated, these game subjects could be further integrated in order to increase the actual mixed game research, and we have not considered how end-user (passenger) characteristics influence their game, or the conclusions of this paper can be generalized to the multienterprise Cournot practice, which represents a direction for future study [41].
6. Conclusion and Policy Implications
By bringing in the factors of local government preference, implementation capacity of the local government, and product competition, this paper studies the policies of local government to regulate irresponsible behaviors in a duopolistic market; analyzes the influence of local government preference and local government implementation capacity on the local government governance policy regarding duopoly enterprises; and explains the phenomenon of local government governance in reality. Thus, the following conclusions can be drawn: (1) the key to regulating irresponsible companies is to make the punishment cost higher than the cost savings for irresponsible behaviors; (2) no matter what the preference of the local government no-governance of online car-hailing service companies’ irresponsible behaviors may persist; and (3) local government ambivalence when regulating irresponsible companies is derived from the complex relationship between social benefits and company interests.
From the above conclusions, we can understand that balancing social benefits and enterprise interests is a difficult problem when it comes to local governmental governance of the irresponsible behaviors of online car-hailing service companies. The traditional means of “governance” tends to make enterprises gradually deviate from social responsibility. As new technology and new commercial activities emerge, the local government should use Internet technology and web-thinking and change from a single-government control approach to a cooperative governance model [42, 43]. As for online car-hailing services and taxis, the cooperative governance model of “local government + platform + driver + passenger” should be used.
(1) Advocating Cautious Governance by the Local Government and Its Playing a Guiding Role. Local government should focus on formulating fair industry rules for online car-hailing service and taxi companies, clarifying the legal relationship between the parties, improving the risk control of market subjects, improving the overall regulatory framework and system, and establishing a national online car-hailing service monitoring platform so that these companies can fully share and dock with local government departmental data platforms and to protect the all-round development of local government information governance systems [44]. Local governments should also actively listen to and widely solicit views from all parties; research and formulate future development planning and policies under national and local laws and governance; regulate qualifications, document issuance, and filing; organize and conduct the evaluation of service quality among enterprises; help enterprises establish and improve their information security and management systems, registration systems, and comprehensive credit evaluation systems; provide information security, confidentiality responsibility, and punishment systems; standardize information collection, processing, storage, and exchange; and implement dynamic supervision [45].
(2) Clarifying the Responsibility and Market Role of Participants, Playing Their Role in Market. Local governments must give full play to the decisive role of the online car-hailing service market in the allocation of resources; ensure the online car-hailing service market subjects are fully developed and have free competition so as to promote the survival of the fittest; and maximize the elimination of contradictions between supply and demand. In the nature of the use, under the framework of national and local government laws and governance, service qualifications should be acquired. Access conditions regarding the appointment of taxi drivers should be strictly reviewed; drivers and companies should sign a formal labor contract; physical health requirements of drivers should be determined; and drivers should have regular medical examination and training. In terms of cost control, enterprises should also pinpoint the conditions for vehicles to access the enterprise platform; comprehensively calculate the enterprise cost; determine the market price basis; and flexibly adjust the price and the number of vehicles according to the actual market supply and demand. In the meantime, enterprises should complete information registration records about drivers who apply for entry to the car-hailing platform in police station [46, 47]. Vehicle satellite positioning devices and emergency alarm devices with a driving record function should be installed. In addition, personal data should be subject to multiple encryption, so as to ensure that it is not at risk of being sold or stolen during transmission.
(3) Cultivating Industry Associations and Developing a Social Organization Supervision Function. Local governments must learn from the experience of the development of social organizations, such as traditional taxi industry associations, and actively cultivate industry associations such as online car-hailing service industry associations and other nongovernmental organizations [48]; establish an industry association management mechanism for online car-hailing service companies; organize seminars led by the association for online car-hailing service companies; develop and constantly improve the corresponding self-discipline measures of the industry; and actively cooperate with the local government in completing corresponding public service security work. In terms of ensuring independence of industry associations, the local government should increase support in industry associations initial stage of development, including finance, taxation, and hiring of personnel, to promote its independent development; establish a sound complaints mechanism so that citizens can participate in the collaborative management of online car-hailing service companies; reward whistleblowing with evidence to solve problems such as hiked prices, poor service quality, and other issues. To ensure these issues can be resolved quickly and appropriately, the local government should collect and collate the feedback in a timely manner and use it as a reference source for governance; for instance, for enterprises that have frequently been complained about, issuance of relevant certifications and so on could be refused the following year, or the company could even be removed from the market.
Conflicts of Interest
The authors declare that there are no conflicts of interest regarding the publication of this paper.
Authors’ Contributions
Xintao Li and Zaisheng Zhang contributed equally to this work.
Acknowledgments
This research was supported by the Projects of the National Social Science Foundation of China (16BGL138), the Projects of the National Social Science Foundation of China (17BTY022), and the Projects of the National Social Science Foundation of China (18CGL018).
[1] X. Cheng, S. Fu, G. de Vreede, "A mixed method investigation of sharing economy driven car-hailing services: Online and offline perspectives," International Journal of Information Management, vol. 41, pp. 57-64, DOI: 10.1016/j.ijinfomgt.2018.03.005, 2018.
[2] S. F. Chan, B. R. Barnes, K. Fukukawa, "Consumer control, dependency and satisfaction with online service," Asia Pacific Journal of Marketing and Logistics, vol. 28 no. 4, pp. 594-615, DOI: 10.1108/APJML-09-2015-0134, 2016.
[3] S. Davidson, G. Wadley, N. Reavley, J. Gunn, S. Fletcher, "Psychological distress and unmet mental health needs among urban taxi drivers: A cross-sectional survey," Australian & New Zealand Journal of Psychiatry, vol. 52 no. 5, pp. 473-482, DOI: 10.1177/0004867417741556, 2018.
[4] M. S. Schwartz, A. B. Carroll, "Corporate social responsibility: A three-domain approach," Business Ethics Quarterly, vol. 13 no. 4, pp. 503-598, DOI: 10.5840/beq200313435, 2003.
[5] H. Larry, "The Rise and Fall of Corporate Social Responsibility," Relations industrielles / Industrial Relations, vol. 73 no. 1, pp. 219-220, 2018.
[6] G. P. Lantos, "The boundaries of strategic corporate social responsibility," Journal of Consumer Marketing, vol. 18 no. 7, pp. 595-630, DOI: 10.1108/07363760110410281, 2001.
[7] L. Albareda, J. M. Lozano, A. Tencati, A. Midttun, F. Perrini, "The changing role of governments in corporate social responsibility: drivers and responses," Business Ethics: A European Review, vol. 17 no. 4, pp. 347-363, DOI: 10.1111/j.1467-8608.2008.00539.x, 2008.
[8] E. Esa, N. A. M. Ghazali, "Corporate social responsibility and corporate governance in Malaysian government-linked companies," Corporate Governance (Bingley), vol. 12 no. 3, pp. 292-305, DOI: 10.1108/14720701211234564, 2012.
[9] D. Geradin, "Uber and the rule of law: Should spontaneous liberalization be applauded or criticized?," Competition Policy International (CPI), vol. 11 no. 1, pp. 22-29, 2015.
[10] F. Song, R. Li, H. Zhou, "Feasibility and issues for establishing network-based carpooling scheme," Pervasive and Mobile Computing, vol. 24,DOI: 10.1016/j.pmcj.2015.05.002, 2015.
[11] H. Hodson, "Call me a cab! Will automatic hailing of Uber taxis by lifestyle apps catch on?," New Scientist, vol. 225 no. 3014, pp. 20-24, DOI: 10.1016/S0262-4079(15)30030-0, 2015.
[12] Y. Tong, W. Jiangning, W. Jianjun, "Duopoly Competition Between Chauffeured Car and Taxi: An Analysis of Pricing and Market Segmentation," Journal of Systems Science and Information, vol. 5 no. 6, pp. 511-523, 2017.
[13] K. Kim, J. D. Lee, "The emergence of the sharing economy: the response strategies of pre-existing taxi industry affected by Uber's disruption," Journal of Systems Science and Information, vol. 7 no. 2, pp. 60-84, 2016.
[14] R. Calo, A. Rosenblat, "The Taking Economy: Uber, Information, and Power," SSRN Electronic Journal,DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.2929643, .
[15] J. Hall, A. Krueger, "An Analysis of the Labor Market for Uber’s Driver-Partners in the United States," National Bureau of Economic Research, vol. no. w22843,DOI: 10.3386/w22843, 2016.
[16] K. Kim, C. Baek, J. Lee, "Creative destruction of the sharing economy in action: The case of Uber," Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice, vol. 110, pp. 118-127, DOI: 10.1016/j.tra.2018.01.014, 2018.
[17] F. Lizeng, KoIllSang, "Factors that Facilitate Using Car Sharing Services with Smart phones: The case of DIDI in China," Journal of Information Technology, vol. 16 no. 2, 2017.
[18] T. Wang, L. Zhao, "The Analysis of Competitive Strategy and Suggestions for Didi under the Background of the New Car-hailing Regulation," Journal of Physics: Conference Series, vol. 910 no. 1, 2017.
[19] H. A. Posen, "Ridesharing in the sharing economy: Should regulators impose Ãber regulations on uber?," Iowa Law Review, vol. 101 no. 1, pp. 405-433, 2015.
[20] F. Zhang, L. Zhang, "Regulation of Car-hailing against the Background of qInternet Plusq in China," Proceedings of the 2nd International Seminar on Education Innovation and Economic Management (SEIEM '17),DOI: 10.2991/seiem-17.2018.19, .
[21] Z. Ruixue, "Analysis on the Policy Agenda Setting of New Car-hailing Regulation from the Perspective of Multiple-Streams Framework," Science & Technology for Development, vol. 4, pp. 243-249, 2017.
[22] M. A. Salman, J. B. Cruz, "An incentive model of duopoly with government coordination," Automatica, vol. 17 no. 6, pp. 821-829, DOI: 10.1016/0005-1098(81)90069-8, 1981.
[23] W. Yu, Y. Yu, "The stability of Bayesian Nash equilibrium of dynamic Cournot duopoly model with asymmetric information," Communications in Nonlinear Science and Numerical Simulation, vol. 63, pp. 101-116, DOI: 10.1016/j.cnsns.2018.03.001, 2018.
[24] Y. Zheng, G. Zhang, W. Zhang, "A Duopoly Manufacturers’ Game Model Considering Green Technology Investment under a Cap-and-Trade System," Sustainability, vol. 10 no. 3,DOI: 10.3390/su10030705, 2018.
[25] Q. Zhang, W. Wang, Y. Peng, Z. Guo, "Impact of rail transport services on port competition based on a spatial duopoly model," Ocean & Coastal Management, vol. 148, pp. 113-130, DOI: 10.1016/j.ocecoaman.2017.06.008, 2017.
[26] N. Ychun, "Luo zhiren., Game Research on Government Regulation and Corporate Social Responsibility in Duopoly Market," Chinese Journal of Management Science, vol. 2, pp. 157-164, 2010.
[27] Y.-F. Chen, "Herd behavior in purchasing books online," Computers in Human Behavior, vol. 24 no. 5, pp. 1977-1992, DOI: 10.1016/j.chb.2007.08.004, 2008.
[28] J. Hedlund, "Imitation in Cournot oligopolies with multiple markets," Economic Theory, vol. 60 no. 3, pp. 567-587, DOI: 10.1007/s00199-015-0878-7, 2015.
[29] G. Dudley, D. Banister, T. Schwanen, "The Rise of Uber and Regulating the Disruptive Innovator," The Political Quarterly, vol. 88 no. 3, pp. 492-499, DOI: 10.1111/1467-923X.12373, 2017.
[30] T. Revell, "Black cabs beat Uber on speed in taxi races," New Scientist, vol. 233 no. 3109,DOI: 10.1016/S0262-4079(17)30113-6, 2017.
[31] S. Harding, M. Kandlikar, S. Gulati, "Taxi apps, regulation, and the market for taxi journeys," Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice, vol. 88, pp. 15-25, DOI: 10.1016/j.tra.2016.03.009, 2016.
[32] K. Basu, P. K. Pattanaik, "Nash equilibria of games when players' preferences are quasi-transitive," International Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 14 no. 1, pp. 61-69, DOI: 10.1111/ijet.12143, 2018.
[33] N. M. Modak, S. Panda, S. S. Sana, "Three-echelon supply chain coordination considering duopolistic retailers with perfect quality products," International Journal of Production Economics,DOI: 10.1016/j.ijpe.2015.05.021, 2015.
[34] T. Natio, "Direct versus indirect environmental regulation in a partially privatized mixed duopoly," Environmental Economics Policy Studies, vol. 4 no. 10, pp. 87-100, 2009.
[35] S. Eaton, G. Kostka, "Central Protectionism in China: The Central SOE Problem in Environmental Governance," China Quarterly, vol. 231, pp. 685-704, DOI: 10.1017/S0305741017000881, 2017.
[36] S. Ohori, "Optimal environmental tax and level of privatization in an international duopoly," Journal of Regulatory Economics, vol. 29 no. 2, pp. 225-233, DOI: 10.1007/s11149-006-6037-0, 2006.
[37] L. F. S. Wang, Yao. Shumei, "Privatization and the environment in a mixed duopoly with pollution Abatement," Economics Bulletin, vol. 29, pp. 3112-3119, 2009.
[38] A. A. Elsadany, "Dynamics of a delayed duopoly game with bounded rationality," Mathematical and Computer Modelling, vol. 52 no. 9-10, pp. 1479-1489, DOI: 10.1016/j.mcm.2010.06.011, 2010.
[39] A. K. Naimzada, L. Sbragia, "Oligopoly games with nonlinear demand and cost functions: two boundedly rational adjustment processes," Chaos, Solitons & Fractals, vol. 29 no. 3, pp. 707-722, DOI: 10.1016/j.chaos.2005.08.103, 2006.
[40] A. Matsumoto, Y. Nonaka, "Statistical Dynamics in a Chaotic Cournot Model With Complementary Goods," Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, vol. 61 no. 4, pp. 532-552, 2008.
[41] J.-N. Louis, A. Caló, K. Leiviskä, E. Pongrácz, "Modelling home electricity management for sustainability: The impact of response levels, technological deployment & occupancy," Energy and Buildings, vol. 119, pp. 218-232, 2016.
[42] C. J. Martin, P. Upham, R. Klapper, "Democratising platform governance in the sharing economy: An analytical framework and initial empirical insights," Journal of Cleaner Production, vol. 166, pp. 1395-1406, DOI: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.08.123, 2017.
[43] M. D. Makowsky, P. E. Smaldino, "The evolution of power and the divergence of cooperative norms," Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, vol. 126, pp. 75-88, DOI: 10.1016/j.jebo.2015.09.002, 2016.
[44] B. Fan, Y. Zhao, "The moderating effect of external pressure on the relationship between internal organizational factors and the quality of open government data," Government Information Quarterly, vol. 34 no. 3, pp. 396-405, DOI: 10.1016/j.giq.2017.08.006, 2017.
[45] Y. Zhang, M. Zhang, Y. Liu, R. Nie, "Enterprise investment, local government intervention and coal overcapacity: The case of China," Energy Policy, vol. 101, pp. 162-169, DOI: 10.1016/j.enpol.2016.11.036, 2017.
[46] Y. Huang, P. Lin, J. Wang, "The influence of bus and taxi drivers’ public self-consciousness and social anxiety on aberrant driving behaviors," Accident Analysis & Prevention, vol. 117, pp. 145-153, DOI: 10.1016/j.aap.2018.04.014, 2018.
[47] D. Gabel, "Uber and the Persistence of Market Power," Journal of Economic Issues, vol. 50 no. 2, pp. 527-534, DOI: 10.1080/00213624.2016.1179060, 2016.
[48] H.-H. Chang, "The economic effects of uber on taxi drivers in Taiwan," Journal of Competition Law and Economics, vol. 13 no. 3, pp. 475-500, DOI: 10.1093/joclec/nhx017, 2017.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer
Copyright © 2018 Xintao Li and Zaisheng Zhang. This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License (the “License”), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. Notwithstanding the ProQuest Terms and Conditions, you may use this content in accordance with the terms of the License. https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/
Abstract
Clarifying the rational choice strategy of local governments and enterprises is crucial for promoting control on the failure of taxis and online car-hailing service companies to fulfill their social responsibilities. The local government can reduce the negative externalities and irresponsibility of such companies by improving the regulatory system; thus, it is important to build a governance model that bridges tradition and modernity. This paper, on the basis of summarizing the achievements of the predecessors, builds a mixed dynamic game model among the local government, online car-hailing service companies, and taxi companies; analyzes the relationship between local government preference, execution, and governance of irresponsible enterprise behaviors; and analyzes the equilibrium solution between local government and duopoly enterprises behavior game deeply. The results show that the key to governance irresponsible companies is to make the punishment cost higher than the cost savings for irresponsible behaviors; no matter what the preference of the local government no-governance of online car-hailing service companies’ irresponsible behaviors may persist; and local government ambivalence when regulating irresponsible companies is derived from the complex relationship between social benefits and company interests. Finally, through the analysis of the equilibrium results for the above model, this paper provides suggestions on regulatory policies so as to provide theoretical support and a decision-making basis for establishing scientific, universal, and feasible governance policies and offering responsible methods of urban transportation.
You have requested "on-the-fly" machine translation of selected content from our databases. This functionality is provided solely for your convenience and is in no way intended to replace human translation. Show full disclaimer
Neither ProQuest nor its licensors make any representations or warranties with respect to the translations. The translations are automatically generated "AS IS" and "AS AVAILABLE" and are not retained in our systems. PROQUEST AND ITS LICENSORS SPECIFICALLY DISCLAIM ANY AND ALL EXPRESS OR IMPLIED WARRANTIES, INCLUDING WITHOUT LIMITATION, ANY WARRANTIES FOR AVAILABILITY, ACCURACY, TIMELINESS, COMPLETENESS, NON-INFRINGMENT, MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. Your use of the translations is subject to all use restrictions contained in your Electronic Products License Agreement and by using the translation functionality you agree to forgo any and all claims against ProQuest or its licensors for your use of the translation functionality and any output derived there from. Hide full disclaimer